M&A AS
A MODERN FORMS OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND INVESTMENT
CROSS-BORDER
MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS
ABSTRACT
xxxx
1. INTRODUCTION
The impact of globalization of markets, complexity of the business environment, volatility, and the need to expand the business multinational,
need modern strategy for external
growth. The importance of foreign
direct investment (FDI) is manifested by acquiring the rights to manage and
control, as well as the right of ownership over the company in which it
invests.
The aim of this paper is to point primarily to the complexity of
the problem of cross-border mergers and acquisitions. In the first part, I points to the role of M&A as a form of
investment in the international market for corporate control. The second part focuses on the motives for the implementation
of cross-border M&A,
and the third part explains the strategy and tactics of their application in
modern business conditions.
2. FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONAL MARKET
CORPORATE CONTROL
The emergence of global markets and directing business
activities across national borders have caused the emergence of new sources of investment capital and a
dispersion (change) in ownership structures. The most prevalent form of ownership in
the company today is the separation of
ownership from management. The high
degree of differences in goals leads
to a significant conflict of interest which
is defined as an agency problem. The goal of the owners is to maximize capital investment of investment capital
and a higher rate of return as expressed in the form of dividends. Enlightened stakeholder model arguing that “to maximize firm value, managers must not only
satisfy, but enlist the support of, all corporate stakeholders”. Enlightened value maximization uses stakeholder theory to consider that a company
cannot maximize value
if any important stakeholder
is ignored or mistreated. However, it maintains “as the criterion for making
the requisite tradeoffs among its stakeholders” long-term value maximization, thereby solving the problems that arise from
considering multiple objectives,
as in traditional stakeholder
theory.
Objective
professional wheel-managers
is to maximize the sake. One of the main areas of disagreement interests of owners of capital and
management structure is the level of risk that is
accepted when making business decisions. From the
standpoint of the owners of capital diversification of investment capital they
are able to reduce the risk of investment. In the decentralized solution, the
organization determines the appropriate performance measure. Person or unit’s
responsibility is to figure out what the performance drivers are, how they
influence performance, and how to manage them. And managers at higher levels
may help the person or unit to understand how to manage them.
When a company becomes a potential prey
for takeover by other companies when does not create added value for
shareholders. Companies
that want to be in a short period of time to consolidate, protect and improve our
competitive position (Petrović & Denčić-Mihajlov, 2010) as
a mechanism of the market for corporate control using merger
and acquisition (M&A)
as a form of foreign direct investment.
Jensen & Ruback (1983) point to the need
to consider responses to the following questions:
a)
What are the goals of Shareholders-acquirer and the target
company?
b)
Should the firm have a single-valued
objective?
c) Does the defense strategy implemented by the
target company may affect the reduction of shareholder wealth?
d)
Does company that
acquires will create market power product?
e)
Does competition legislation imposes
additional costs of a company takeover?
The debate over
question: corporations should maximize value or act in the interests of their stakeholders, framed as stockholders versus stakeholders, or whether the
firm should have a single-valued objective function or
scorecard. Proposition: single-valued objective is a prerequisite
for purposeful or rational behavior by any organization.Those in support of shareholder wealth maximization, argue that the most realistic for a
firm is to have a single-valued
prioritized objective,
rather than myriads of them; Hitt et al. (2009) suggest that mergers
and acquisitions reduce the transaction costs of entering new markets, yet
there is still a high level of transaction costs relating to the
process of adapting to the new
market of location, cultural and regulatory aspects.
Thomas & Grosse (2001)
indicate different groups of factors that affect the investment
decision making:
a) economic factors
such as the characteristics of the market and
the efficiency of investments;
b) socio-political factors such as the impact of the macro environment on the company's operations (the
degree of market orientation of the country, the existing infrastructure,
protection of the environment, the characteristics of the legal system of the
country);
c) geographic distance. Country's investment location may
be affected by the reduction of transport and communication costs.
Main motiv of foreign companies is profit. Ownership advantage can be inmaterial form (a competitive product, technology) or intangible form (patent, brand) and results in a utility
in the expansion of production in the international market or licensing. For
a country of investment investments in the form of m erdžera
and acquisitions represent a change in
ownership structure the undertaking which is the subject of investing. The positive side of this type of investment lies in improving the operations of the enterprise, the
modern corporate management and technological competence in the international
market. The significance is higher if
the country is investing transition or a developing country, and the
origin of investment capital from the developed countries. The corporate objective function that maximizes social welfare thus becomes
“maximize current total firm market value.” It tells firms to expand output and investment to the
point where the present market value
of the firm is at a maximum.
3. MOTIVES OF INTERNATIONAL M&A
Numerous
scholars have conducted empirical studijei developed a number of theories and hypotheses about the
motives of international mergers and
acquisitions. The set of theories
and hypotheses investigated the
reaction of the management structure the company to changes in the environment. Passive
reaction manifests itself in response to changes in the
environment, while active responses based on strategic
planning. Goar (1969) proposes a theory of the disorder (disturbance
theory) by which the differences in
expectations of shareholder cause the action frequently changed owners. This suggests that
when it comes to economic turbulence, the owners of the target company will be
more pessimistic and the company that acquires more optimistic mood regarding the evaluation of the target company, which
eventually results in the realization of the
company takeover.
Jensen believes the inherent conflict between the doctrine of shareholder value maximization and the objectives of stakeholder theory can be
resolved by melding together “enlightened” versions of these two philosophies:
“Enlightened value maximization recognizes that communication with
and motivation of an organization’s managers, employees, and partners is
extremely difficult.” In short, says that a firm cannot maximize value if it ignores or
mistreats any important stakeholder
group. By the same token, the enlightened stakeholder theory implies that firm value is the goal, but the
processes and the audits suggested by the stakeholder theorists should form the basis of
action towards motivating all the key stakeholders (Jensen, 2001:16). What we must do, however, is to set
up our organizations so that managers and employees are clearly motivated to
seek value.
Every firm has to develop its own growth strategy according
to its own characteristics and environment. Internal growth strategy can take
place either by expansion, diversification and modernisation. External growth is a process where two organisation comes together for the
achievement of common goal. Foreign collaboration
helps in removing financial, technological and managerial gap in the developing
countries. It is recognised as an important supplement for development of the
country and for securing scientific and technical know-how[1].
Theory macroeconomic shocks
(Macroeconomic shocks theory) lists factors such as economic growth, interest rates or inflation (Wang,
2008). GDP
growth and lower interest rates cheapen the a company takeover process and
make the implementation of mergers and acquisitions more likely.
Companies which using the Theory of Monopoly (Monopoly theory) increase
monopolistic market position create barriers to entry for other companies in
the market, realizing external growth
(Stigler, 1950). The theory wrong assessment of the market (Market
(mis)-valuation hypothesis) is based on an inefficient capital market and indicates that due
to asymmetric information about the target company its market price does not
reflect its true value. Most empirical studies speak
in favor decrease the value for shareholders for company that acquires (Wang,
2008), which explains the behavior
of managers and decision-makers on the takeover of the target company on behalf
of their own interests at the expense of shareholders. In this sense, the theory
of "managerial Empire" (Empire-building hypothesis) argues that in situations with less able to
control the work of managers by shareholders may be directing
the company to grow above its optimal size. This further leads to the growth of cost asymmetries
and increased use of personal benefits by managers. Theory managers pride (Hubris theory) is based on the view that individuals not always bring rational decisions under
conditions of uncertainty. Managers depending on the situation
suits them, they can to convince shareholders that the market does not show the real economic value of the target or
integrated companies and that their assessment of the correct valuation (Wang
& Moin, 2012).
With Enlightened value maximization Jensen (2001) proposes a new vision for both
approaches, the Enlightened Value
maximization and Enlightened Stakeholder theory. According to Jensen (2001), the enlightened value maximization would
assume many of the characteristics of stakeholder theory, but also accept the maximization of total long-term firm market value as a criterion to make
the necessary tradeoffs among its stakeholders. Jensen’s new approaches pointed out that the maximization of long-term
firm market value seems
to be a necessary condition to keep the corporate investment in relationships with stakeholders. As Jensen
points out, the Balanced Scorecard likewise does not provide a single objective standard for
guiding how to weigh financial, customer, internal business process, learning
and growth and other dimensions that together make up the ―scorecard.. Balanced Scorecard
theory is flawed because it presents managers with a scorecard which gives no
score--that is, no single-valued
measure of how they have performed. Thus managers evaluated with such a system […] have no way to make principled or purposeful decisions.
The solution is to define a true measuring performance for the organization or
division.
Defining motives realization of cross-border M&A is defined bythe degree of
efficiency of the capital market or the rationality of decision makers. In one aspect, the M&A operationalization of strategic
development for the company, and the other as a result of
passive response to changes in the company's environment or irrational behavior
of decision makers.
3.1. INCREASE
COMPETITIVENESS
The global market and changes in the
competitive environmentmake it possible for the formation of large
multinational companies. Evenett (2004) states that the
integration of national markets to developing countries and transition
contributes to increase sustainability and reduce monopolistic behavior of
companies. The strategy of these countries to attract foreign investment capital, and in order to provide access to new markets and
technological developments, while the strategy of large companies that through cross-border merger
and acquisition activity shorten the period of entry into the global market. For
developing countries in transition is characteristic that the main contribution to shaping the competitive
environment provides state structure through policy
stimulus in the area of macroeconomic stabilization, price and trade
liberalization, privatization and the establishment of institutional and legal
framework as the basis for the development of a market economy. The geographical presence of the company in those markets
where it has not had a share not rare to be a condition of survival, not one of
the commercial alternatives. The dilemma: whether the
target market to build new capacity or to buy existing ones. Purchase of existing capacity is financially profitable,
the time aspect ROI quickly achievable.
The effects of economies of scale reduction of costs per unit Product opens space for the elimination of duplicate
functions, reduces the risk of business operations and opens up new
possibilities in the field of manufacturing, marketing, purchasing and sales,
research and development.
The effect of the depth of the economy often appears as the main motive of international
acquisitions in the financial sector. The effect contributes to competitive advantage because
the companycan use one set of inputs in
the production of a wide range of products and services (Denčić-Mihajlov,
2009). Incurred within one company (transaction costs) can be
reduced vertical merger.
3.2. RESPONSE TO CHANGES
IN THE ENVIRONMENT
The strategy of external growth in the form of M&A target companies the ability to overcome numerous
constraints such asaccess to the
necessary resources, financial resources, outdated technology, the saturation /
insufficiency of the domestic marketand
slow adaptation to changes in market conditions. These companies have an intense to development of techniques and technologies and access to new knowledge and skills in order to
provide a competitive product. The
legislation bars represent a significant determinant of the
performance of post acquisition period, refers to the protection of shareholders, accounting standards and the taxability of acquisitions (Rossi & Volpin,
2004). When the taxable merger, the
assets of the acquired firm is revalued as a result of the revaluation in the
form of attribution of value or write-off is treated as taxable income or loss
(Brealey & Myers, 2003). Multinational companies have the role of supplier of
technology to developing countries and transition economies.
3.3. INEFFICIENT CAPITAL MARKET
The most important participants the capital market investors -the
owners of capital. In the corporate
business environment the main task is to contribute to increasing the value of the share capital. In contrast, the wide
dispersion of ownership increases the room for maneuver managers. Companies that are included in an activity that is
not related to the activity of the company, bidders can be initiated motives managers who are not of an
economic nature. Realization takeover could have negative consequences if there is no profit, where
the final outcome can be reducing the
price of shares of company that acquires, inability to pay dividends, not
rare and ruin the investment project. Serving managers that his assessment more
valid than the market, over-confidence, arrogance, contributes to greater complexity of the agency
problem. One reason for this
behavior is the tendency of managers to preserve acquired high positions in the
company.
Maximization of the total market value of the firm is the best objective function that will guide their managers to conduct
appropriate tradeoff among
its various stakeholders.
Enlightened stakeholder
model arguing that “to maximize firm value, managers must not only satisfy, but enlist the support of,
all corporate stakeholders”. This is an
advantage of Jensen‘s, furthermore, he explains, "top management plays a
critical role in this function
through its leadership and effectiveness in creating, projecting and sustaining
the company’s strategic vision" (Jensen, 2010, p.33). The answers to the
questions of how managers should define better vs. worse, and how managers in
fact do define it, have important implications for social welfare. Asking
manager to maximize profits, market share, future growth in profits and anything
one pleases leave him/her without decision objective. The result would be confusion and
fundamentally handicap the firm in its competition for survival (Jensen, Wruck
and Barry, 1991). Managers must pay attention to all constituencies that
can affect the value of
the firm. Customers want low prices, high quality, and full service. Employees
want high wages, high-quality working conditions, and fringe benefits,
including vacations, medical benefits, and pensions. Suppliers of capital want
low risk and high returns.
objective function is at the core of any decision criterion—must specify
how to make the tradeoffs between these demands. There is simply no principled
way within the stakeholder
construct that anyone could say that a manager has done a good or bad job. One
of the most important jobs of managers, complementing objective measures of performance with
managerial subjective evaluation of subtle interdependencies and other factors
is exactly what most managers would like to avoid. Stakeholder theory giving managers more power
to do whatever they want, imposed by forces outside the firm—financial markets,
corporate control
(takeovers), and, product markets. Given a dozen or two dozen measures and no
sense of the tradeoffs between them, the typical manager will be unable to
behave purposefully, and the result will be confusion. And without specifying
what the tradeoffs are among these two dozen or so different measures, there is
no “balance” in their scorecard.
4. MERGERS AND ACQUISITION STRATEGY AND TACTICS
Depending on the target that the company
wants to achieve strategies merger / takeover could be focused on horizontal,
vertical or conglomerate integration. Merger is a form of a negotiated merger of two companies, in
which consent is required a minimum of half of the shareholders of
both companies. Acquisitions are more common in practice, for company
that acquires tactic means that
companies carry out good assessment of investment, facilitate minimizing transaction
costs and increase
the positive outcome of the post- acquisition period.
Takeover tactics must be set to its realization contributes to increasing shareholder wealth without jeopardizing the interests of employees in
the company nor the interests of its creditors, and in accordance with legal regulations. Some of the modern tactics of a company takeover are:
1.
Tactics purchasing shares on the open market;
2.
Takeover
control over the company by fighting agent;
3.
Friendly takeover by
negotiating the sale of shares and
4.
Realization
of public takeover bid (Denčić-Mihajlov,
2009).
Tactic purchasing shares on the open market with an applied when
acquirer does not want to disclose their intentions, striving
d and as soon as possible buy a
controlling stake before the
managers of target companies have been informed that there has been a change of
ownership and take adequate defense strategy. Shareholders who have
a minority share in the ownership structure may delegate their right
to vote on representatives,usually investment banks, lawyers or specialized brokerage
firm.the role of MPs to representing the interests of one or more shareholders
to influence business decisions in favor of their principals. Negotiations on the sale of
shares representing friend takeover that are implemented by direct negotiation between company that acquires and target companies and usually
involves a sale of the entire company. This tactic cost can be very
popular. In case of cancellation of the agreed conditions or their disrespect can result in relatively high price. Takeover tactics is the most
common form of acquisitions. In
order to protect shareholders a large number of countries precisely defines the
conditions in which this type of a company takeover can be implemented. European Parliament Directive (2004/25
/ EC) regulation issues related
to the trade of securities, shareholder
protection and providing equal
opportunities for all potential investors. Defining the price offered is a very
important aspect, because it must be high
enough to be attractive to shareholders, but not so high that the
acquirer is in a position to prepaid the value of the redeemed shares, thus jeopardizing future profitability.
5. INTERNATIONAL
EXPERIENCE AND EFFECTS OF IMPLEMENTATION OF M&A
M&A are present in the sector of
production and services alike (a automotive industry, chemical, pharmaceutical, oil, financial
and telecommunications services).
The economic history has been divided into Merger Waves based on the
merger activities in the business world as:
Period
|
Name
|
Facet
|
1893–1904
|
First Wave
|
Horizontal
mergers
|
1919–1929
|
Second Wave
|
Vertical
mergers
|
1955–1970
|
Third Wave
|
Diversified
conglomerate mergers
|
1974–1989
|
Fourth Wave
|
Co-generic
mergers; Hostile takeovers; Corporate Raiding
|
1993–2000
|
Fifth Wave
|
Cross-border
mergers, mega-mergers
|
2003–2008
|
Sixth Wave
|
Globalisation,
Shareholder Activism, Private Equity, LBO
|
2014-
|
Seventh Wave
|
Source:
http://www.kpmg.com/ZA/en/IssuesAndInsights/ArticlesPublications/Transactions-Restructuring/Pages/Seventh-Wave-of-MA.aspx
(11.03.2016)
The first wave of M&A
activities will start in 1893, and is characterized by the integration of predominantly horizontal type which caused the creation of a monopolistic market
structure and the large monopolies: Du Pont, US Steel, Standard Oil, General Electric, Eastman Kodak,
American Tobacco (Denčić-Mihajlov, 2009). Oligopolistic
structures characteristic of the second
wave, which began in 1910, when
they arise giants like General Motors, IBM, John Dere and others. The third cycle began in the mid-twentieth century and
led to a change in the way of funding
acquisitions, a number of
integration conglomerate diverification companies activity in
various sectors of industry. The
fourth wave is characterized by an increase in the number of hostile takeovers, resulting in the emergence of more subtle tactics, and
an increase in speculative stock market
activities as well as the collapse of the bond market low rating. The very end of the
twentieth century was marked by the fifth wave of M&A
activity,which is still ongoing, and
characterized by a reduced number of
hostile takeovers and increased participation of strategic approaches.
According to data from UNCTAD (2013), the
share of M&A
in the total foreign investment was growing until the outbreak of the economic
and financial crisis of 2008, when it came to a sudden drop of investment
activities in general. Over the 2003-2005
period, developed countries accounted for 85% of the USD 465 billion
cross-border M&As, 47% and 23% of which respectively pertain EU15 and US
firms either as acquirer or as target countries. According to the Baker & McKenzie (2013) in the financial services sector slowdown and increasing regulatory constraints that
characterize the developed markets, as well as a better competitive conditions
tend to result in an increase in cross-border transactions. The energy sector, natural
resources and mining is characterized by an increase in demand at the global
level, which is most pronounced in China, India and Russia. The largest number of M&A in developing countries were
implemented in the energy sector. According to the report,
Clifford Chance (2012) M&A activity in
2012 in the mining industry are intense on the Australian market, while
telecommunications, media and technology in the first half was characterized by
a decline in these activities in general. The increase is noticeable only in the field of technology, which
initiated the diversification of products and the need for rapid growth. The health sector is characterized by intense M&A activity in
China, where the government is a significant increase in interest from foreign
companies that are trying to overcome regulatory barriers and establish a
partnership with the local companies, even when it involves the transfer of
control.
6. METHODOLOGY
2.1. Estimation strategy to model cross-border M&As
We follow Head and Ries (2005, 2007) to model the location
decision of multinational firms through M&As[2].
the probability pij that a randomly drawn company from country i acquires a
randomly drawn target in country j. Using the total stock of targets in country
j (kj ) and the total number of potential acquiring company in country i (mi),
the expected value of mergers and acquisitions (M&Aij ) between country i
and j is:
E(M&Aij ) = mipijkj
Assume also that net profits from an acquiring company si
in country (i) for an investment in country j are [πi−σtij+εsij ], where πi is
the discounted value of the gross profits due to the profitability of the
merger, tij denote transaction costs between markets i and j (note that tij can
be a multidimensional vector) and εsij is random term of unobserved firm level
characteristics, independently distributed with Type I Extreme value cumulative
distribution (CDF(ε) = exp(− exp(−ε))). Using discrete choice theory (see Mac
Fadden (1974)), one can show that under such assumptions:
pij = exp(πi − σtij ) l ml exp(πl − σtlj ) (2)
where the probability to win the bid for a firm in country
i is positively related to the discounted value of its expected profits and
negatively related to transaction costs; but it also depends on the position of
all the potential competitors, Bj = l ml exp(πl − σtlj ), with respect to
market j. Using the latter expression, we get:
E(M&Aij ) = mi exp(πi − σtij ) Bj kj (3)
where Bj is a measure of the “financial remoteness” of
market j. The interpretation of this term is clearcut: (i) the higher the
discounted value of the expected profits of all other potential buyers or (ii)
the easier it is for all potential acquiring firms to buy a target firm in
country j, the more difficult it is for a firm in country i to compete on such
an asset. Given the analogy with the “multilateral resistance factor” developed
in the trade literature (Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003)), Bj is alike the
“market potential” (or “supplier access”). We can rewrite (3) as follows:
E(M&Aij ) = exp
(log(mi) + log(kj ) − log(Bj ) + πi − σtij ) (4)
where mi and kj are related to market sizes, πi is related
to the profitability of investments in country i and tij is related to
transaction costs between markets.
We can therefore use the gravity equations framework to
estimate the impact of various determinants of cross-border M&A in a given
sector s, which takes the following form
12 M&Aij,s,t = eαieαj eαt eαs (Gdpi,s,t Gdpj,s,t) βZθ
ij,s,tηij,s,t (5)
where M&Aij,s,t denotes M&A between source country
i (acquirer) and host country j (target) at time t in sector s, Gdpi,s,t (resp.
Gdpj,s,t) stands for the market size of sector s in country i (resp. j),
Zij,s,t is a set of control variables (linked to expected profitability of
firms, transactions costs and other barriers) that might affect cross-border
M&A and αi, αj , αt and αs are the source and host country fixed effects, a
time-fixed effect and a sectoral fixed-effect respectively. ηij,s,t is an error
term assumed to be statistically independent of the regressors.
The use of acquirer/target fixed-effects is necessary to
control for unobservable countries characteristics in order to limit potential
biases due to omitted variables in the estimation. In particular, it allows to
control for the “financial remoteness” Bj of some host markets (assumed to be
constant over time). We also control for time fixed-effects since cross-border
M&As have been strongly increasing over time due to increasing financial
integration across countries. As for Zij,s,t, we assume that they are function
of geography, institutions and financial variables capturing expected
profitability of firms. Variables are described in detail in the following
subsections.
2.2 Description of the data on mergers and acquisitions
I using Thomson Financial (SDC Platinum) over the 1985-2004
period (10 manufacturing and 10 service sectors) described in the Appendix
(section 7.2)
The most important acquiring manufacturing sectors in terms
of size accounting for almost three quarters of global M&As in manufacturing
are (i) chemicals, petroleum, coal, rubber and plastic products, (ii) machinery
and equipment, and (iii) food, beverages and tobacco. We divide the twenty
years sectoral observations in two main groups: 1) M&As occuring within the
same sector (“within sectors”): acquirer and target firms belong to the same
sector. 2) M&As occuring across sectors (“across sectors”): the acquirer
firm is targeting a firm whose main activity does not belong to the sector of
the acquirer (according to our level of disaggregation).
2.3 Description of the regressors
Following expression (5), we study M&As by assessing
the roles of market size, transaction costs and firms’ expected profitability.
The first key variable is sectoral GDP in the source and the host country at time
t. We restrict the elasticity to be the same for country i and country j by
using the log of the product of the two GDPs at date t (log(Gdpi,s,t
Gdpj,s,t)), but none of the results depend on this restriction. two different
dummies constructed as Emui,t Emuj,t is equal to one if both countries belong
to EMU at time t and zero otherwise; nonEmui,t Emuj,t is equal to one when the
host country j belongs to the euro zone but not the source country. We also
control for the market value-GDP ratio of the target country j, as M&As
might be more likely when foreign capital is more economical (Baker, Foley and
Wurgler (2008))
The descriptive statistics concerning the sectoral
indicators (across countries and across sectors).
7. DATA
7.1. Descriptive statistics
Sample: - Annual data over the period 1985-2004 - 21 source
countries and 31 target countries - 10 manufacturing sectors and 10 service
sectors.
Table 1. Inward and outward foreign direct
investment flows, annual, 2008-2013
DIRECTION
|
Inward
|
MEASURE
|
US Dollars at current prices and current
exchange rates in millions
|
|||
YEAR
|
2008
|
2009
|
2010
|
2011
|
2012
|
2013
|
ECONOMY
|
||||||
Albania
|
974,3333
|
995,9299
|
1050,708
|
876,268
|
855,4405
|
1225,494
|
Austria
|
6858,315
|
9303,418
|
839,6851
|
10617,85
|
3939,385
|
11082,65
|
Belgium
|
193950,3
|
60963,29
|
77013,95
|
119021,9
|
-30261,1
|
-2405,87
|
Bosnia
|
1001,648
|
249,9485
|
406,0295
|
493,3402
|
366,3095
|
331,716
|
Croatia
|
5938,058
|
3346,352
|
489,9753
|
1516,802
|
1355,508
|
580,1199
|
Cyprus
|
1413,993
|
3472,128
|
765,5472
|
2384,112
|
1257,336
|
533,2833
|
Czech Republic
|
6451,003
|
2926,815
|
6140,583
|
2317,554
|
7984,109
|
4990,445
|
Estonia
|
1731,144
|
1839,952
|
1598,357
|
340,4763
|
1516,79
|
949,8089
|
Finland
|
-1144
|
717,6565
|
7358,833
|
2549,84
|
4152,672
|
-1064,85
|
France
|
64184,28
|
24215
|
33628,46
|
38547,03
|
25085,64
|
4875,465
|
Germany
|
8108,646
|
23788,52
|
65619,93
|
59317,03
|
13203,24
|
26720,79
|
Greece
|
4498,627
|
2436,365
|
330,0739
|
1143,135
|
1740,101
|
2566,523
|
Ireland
|
-16452,9
|
25715,33
|
42804,07
|
23544,7
|
38314,57
|
35519,72
|
Italy
|
-10835,3
|
20076,6
|
9178,261
|
34323,8
|
92,51003
|
16507,8
|
Latvia
|
1261,391
|
93,9373
|
379,5297
|
1465,747
|
1109,321
|
808,3462
|
Luxembourg
|
16853,28
|
19313,9
|
39730,84
|
18116,2
|
9526,574
|
30075,37
|
Malta
|
943,412
|
411,6802
|
924,2446
|
275,9173
|
4,125305
|
-2099,76
|
Montenegro
|
960,4233
|
1527,259
|
760,4408
|
558,0527
|
619,7529
|
447,3504
|
Netherlands
|
4549,31
|
38609,95
|
-7324,33
|
21046,63
|
9705,715
|
24388,87
|
Portugal
|
4664,862
|
2706,38
|
2645,813
|
11149,63
|
8994,983
|
3114,022
|
Serbia
|
3492,097
|
2358,11
|
1813,056
|
3256,788
|
659,4051
|
1377,417
|
Slovakia
|
4868,024
|
-6,0791
|
1769,761
|
3491,286
|
2825,923
|
590,9695
|
Slovenia
|
1947,486
|
-658,56
|
360,005
|
997,6576
|
-59,4377
|
-678,582
|
Spain
|
76992,51
|
10406,6
|
39872,51
|
28379,21
|
25696,45
|
39166,6
|
Table 2. Goods and Services (BPM6): Exports and
imports of goods and services, annual, 2005-2014
MEASURE
|
USD in millions
|
SERIES
|
Total trade in goods
|
FLOW
|
Exports
|
YEAR
|
2010
|
2011
|
2012
|
2013
|
2014
|
ECONOMY
|
|||||
Individual economies
|
_
|
_
|
_
|
_
|
_
|
Albania
|
736,926
|
962,078
|
1124,33
|
1411,45
|
1231,96
|
Austria
|
145021,8
|
170050,9
|
160172,1
|
163510
|
164146,1
|
Belgium
|
271308,3
|
323428,6
|
303389,2
|
321893,5
|
325189
|
Bosnia and
Herzegovina
|
3230,77
|
4109,86
|
3837,31
|
4363,28
|
4490,23
|
Bulgaria
|
20583,8
|
28248,2
|
26677,7
|
28159,13
|
27903,46
|
Croatia
|
10683,72
|
12181,47
|
11139,43
|
11853,38
|
13480,49
|
Cyprus
|
2281,94
|
2748,17
|
2590,62
|
3648,632
|
4199,111
|
Czech Republic
|
115008,2
|
137794,4
|
134056,9
|
137002
|
146635,3
|
Estonia
|
9909,078
|
14434,88
|
14266,72
|
15119,52
|
15127,81
|
Finland
|
66974,42
|
79036,36
|
73015,38
|
73825,04
|
76144,25
|
France
|
507441,3
|
586278
|
560095,5
|
580675,5
|
581452,8
|
Germany
|
1216272
|
1431995
|
1380059
|
1438654
|
1490934
|
Greece
|
22243,71
|
27413,45
|
27903,34
|
29543,56
|
31153,02
|
Hungary
|
87566,17
|
99806,08
|
90208,58
|
96090,07
|
99922,65
|
Ireland
|
116384,4
|
125571,4
|
117232,6
|
121813,4
|
142247
|
Italy
|
446870,5
|
522556,8
|
500742,7
|
503453,2
|
513931,4
|
Latvia
|
8816,693
|
11538,11
|
12393,77
|
13025,14
|
13419,91
|
Lithuania
|
19722,14
|
26999,05
|
28815,59
|
31862,59
|
31562,72
|
Luxembourg
|
19818,69
|
23737,93
|
22354,02
|
23975,02
|
24208,9
|
Malta
|
3346,68
|
3951,16
|
4105,261
|
3799,596
|
3442,209
|
Montenegro
|
449,069
|
653,931
|
498,566
|
525,273
|
479,325
|
Netherlands
|
477184,8
|
554309,1
|
544084,9
|
566035,9
|
570923,8
|
Norway
|
129119
|
164773
|
159825
|
153521
|
146231,6
|
Poland
|
159570,1
|
184242
|
181326,7
|
197662,6
|
208938,7
|
Portugal
|
48891,13
|
58797,12
|
56981,04
|
61848,83
|
62867,26
|
Romania
|
43462,31
|
55746,61
|
51207,38
|
58278,66
|
62106,51
|
Serbia
|
10198,56
|
11748,1
|
10792,8
|
14010,3
|
15285,59
|
Slovakia
|
64003,2
|
79215,9
|
80751,1
|
82742,8
|
83219,8
|
Slovenia
|
24675,35
|
29251,2
|
27309,73
|
28800,03
|
30674,07
|
Spain
|
254172,8
|
306139,9
|
293952,9
|
310748,7
|
317049,4
|
Sweden
|
167215,3
|
197103,8
|
184634,9
|
181128,7
|
178556,4
|
Switzerland
|
277166
|
345691
|
332472
|
373459
|
327570
|
Turkey
|
120992
|
142392
|
161948
|
161789
|
168935
|
Ukraine
|
47299
|
62383
|
64427
|
59106
|
50552
|
United Kingdom
|
418766,2
|
495394
|
482013
|
479725,6
|
486292,4
|
World
|
14901483
|
17965411
|
18147645
|
18545295
|
18688979
|
Developing economies
|
6326503
|
7823809
|
8194084
|
8425328
|
8467947
|
Transition economies
|
597222,1
|
797991,6
|
817099,8
|
800900,7
|
763124,8
|
Developed economies
|
7977757
|
9343611
|
9136461
|
9319067
|
9457906
|
Developed economies:
Europe
|
5257362
|
6218464
|
5976504
|
6209525
|
6296878
|
High-income economies (IBRD)
|
10215947
|
12232717
|
12217999
|
12439771
|
12498747
|
CEFTA
|
18407,58
|
22561,96
|
20911,08
|
25374,54
|
26937,97
|
EFTA
|
410406,7
|
515315,9
|
496904,9
|
531572,7
|
478649,9
|
EU28 (European Union)
|
4845769
|
5701782
|
5478294
|
5676492
|
5816730
|
Euro area
|
3725339
|
4377453
|
4210216
|
4374975
|
4481892
|
Europe
|
5740249
|
6859746
|
6634851
|
6853821
|
6907867
|
8. RESULTS
Among developed
economies, European MNEs are the most upbeat about global FDI prospects (see
figure I.24), despite continuing concern about the EU regional economy. These
expectations arise from factors such as the quantitative easing programme
launched by the European Central Bank; the considerable cash holdings
accumulated by major MNEs in the region; the attractiveness for foreign
investors of firms, in particular SMEs, based in weaker EU economies;10 and
MNEs’ consolidation strategies in industries such as pharmaceuticals and
telecommunications. In contrast, executives from Latin America, North America
and other developed economies (Australia, Japan, New Zealand, etc.) are less
optimistic about global FDI prospects.
Significant momentum for cross-border M&As,
decline in greenfield FDI projects.4
After two consecutive
years of decline, M&A activity resumed growth in 2014 (figure I.10). In net
terms,5 the value of cross-border M&As increased by 28 per cent
over 2013, reaching almost $400 billion. MNEs have gradually regained the
confidence to go back on the acquisition trail.
The value of
cross-border M&As in developed economies increased by 16 per cent and those
in developing and transition economies by 66 per cent. Investors’ appetite for
new greenfield investment projects is less buoyant. After a first rebound in
2013, the total value of announced greenfield investment declined slightly by 2
per cent, remaining close to the $700 billion level of 2013. In particular, in
2014 the value of greenfield projects in developed and developing economies was
substantially unchanged compared with 2013 (annual growth rates of −1 per cent
in both groupings), while transition economies saw a considerable fall (−13 per
cent).
Figure 1. Value of cross-border M&As and announced
greenfield projects, 2003−2014 (Billions of dollars)
Source: UNCTAD,
cross-border M&A database for M&As (www.unctad.org/fdistatistics); Financial Times Ltd, fDi Markets (www.fDimarkets.com) for greenfield projects.
FDI flows to Europe also
fell by 11 per cent to $289 billion. Among European economies, inflows
decreased in Ireland, Belgium, France and Spain while they increased in the
United Kingdom, Switzerland and Finland.Germany became the largest investing
country in Europe.
United States companies
represented an attractive target, absorbing more than one third of the largest
M&A acquisitions globally. European MNEs targeted the United States market,
in particular pharmaceutical firms but also other industries. For example,
Germany-based Bayer purchased the consumer care business of Merck for $14.2
billion, and Swiss Roche Holding acquired Intermune for $8.3 billion. In
January 2014, Italian automaker Fiat completed its acquisition of Chrysler for
$3.65 billion, gaining full ownership. Large M&A deals in Europe occurred
predominantly in the telecommunications industry. Of the five largest
acquisitions in Europe, three were in telecommunications, and all were led by
other European MNEs. The largest deal was the acquisition of SFR SA (France) by
Altice SA (Luxembourg) for $23 billion.
The value of sales of
MNEs’ stakes in foreign entities (divestments,6 including sales to domestic
firms or to other MNEs) reached a record high in 2014, at $511 billion, a 56
per cent increase over 2013 (figure I.11) and the highest value since 2008.
This value was split almost equally in transactions between sales to other MNEs
(52 per cent) and transfers from MNEs to domestic companies (48 per cent).
Among developed
economies, European MNEs are the most upbeat about global FDI prospects (see
figure I.24), despite continuing concern about the EU regional economy. These
expectations arise from factors such as the quantitative easing programme
launched by the European Central Bank; the considerable cash holdings
accumulated by major MNEs in the region; the attractiveness for foreign
investors of firms, in particular SMEs, based in weaker EU economies;10
and MNEs’ consolidation strategies in industries such as pharmaceuticals and
telecommunications. In contrast, executives from Latin America, North America
and other developed economies (Australia, Japan, New Zealand, etc.) are less
optimistic about global FDI prospects.
Factors such as
substantial investment in infrastructure (especially in information and
communication technology (ICT)), a strong skills base, political stability and
proximity to Europe make Morocco well placed to attract services FDI.
In South-East Europe, foreign investors mostly
targeted manufacturing. In contrast to previous years, when
the largest share of FDI flows was directed to the financial, construction and
real estate industries, in 2014 foreign investors targeted manufacturing,
buoyed on the back of competitive production costs and access to EU markets.
Serbia and Albania, both EU accession candidates, remained the largest
recipients of FDI flows in the subregion at $2 billion and $1 billion,
respectively
Geopolitical risk and regional conflict weighed
heavily on FDI flows to the transition economies of the CIS. FDI
flows to Ukraine fell by 91 per cent to $410 million − the lowest level in 15
years − mainly due to the withdrawal of capital by Russian investors, and
investors based in Cyprus (partly linked to roundtripping from the Russian
Federation and Ukraine). The Russian Federation − the region’s largest host
country − saw its flows fall by 70 per cent to $21 billion because of the
country’s negative growth prospects as an well as an adjustment after the
exceptional level reached in 2013 (due to the large-scale Rosneft−BP
transaction (WIR14)).
Direct impact on FDI inflows. In
the last 10 years, annual FDI inflows to the Russian Federation grew almost
five-fold, from $15 billion in 2004 to $69 billion in 2013, before they fell
dramatically in 2014. Driven by high expected rates of return, foreign MNEs
increased their investments in energy and natural-resourcesrelated projects. Foreign
investors have entered the Russian energy market mainly through two channels:
asset swaps and technology provision deals. Oil and gas firms of the Russian
Federation were allowed to enter downstream markets in developed countries in
exchange for allowing MNEs from those countries to take minority participations
in those firms’ domestic exploration and extraction projects. For example,
Wintershall (Germany) acquired a stake in the YuzhnoRusskoye gas field in
Siberia, and Eni (Italy) gained access to exploration and production facilities
in the Russian Federation. In return, Gazprom (Russian Federation) acquired
parts of those companies’ European assets in hydrocarbons transportation,
storage and distribution. In some oil and gas projects that require high
technology, such as the development of the Shtokman field, the involvement of
developedcountry MNEs such as StatoilHydro (Norway) and Total (France) was
necessary because of their expertise.
After a period of
growth, FDI in natural-resourcesrelated industries has come to a standstill.
Sanctions have had an impact on both channels. For example, in November 2014,
BASF (Germany) and Gazprom (Russian Federation) agreed to scrap a $14.7 billion
asset swap that would have given Gazprom full control of a jointly operated
European gas trading and storage business, including the biggest underground
gas storage facility in Europe. In return, BASF’s Wintershall affiliate was set
to gain stakes in two west Siberian gas fields.29 The oil industry
was also affected by a ban on the exports of a wide range of goods, services
and technology to Russian oil projects, in particular those in Arctic,
deep-water and shale areas. The enormous Siberian oilfields developed in Soviet
times are ageing, and without the development of new resources − from the
Arctic to Siberia − Russian oil production could fall. Some foreign affiliates
have already begun to hold back in some projects in the Arctic. For example,
ExxonMobil (United States) had to freeze all 10 of its joint ventures with Rosneft
in this region, including the Kara Sea project. Similarly, a Shell (United
States) joint project with Gazprom Neft for the development of the Bazhenov
field had to be suspended, as did the Total (France) project with Lukoil.
Europe was host to inflows
worth $289 billion (down 11 per cent from 2013) accounting for 24 per cent of
the world total in 2014. Inflows fell in 18 European economies, including major
recipients in 2013 such as Belgium, France and Ireland. In contrast, some of
the European countries that made the largest gains in 2014 were those that had
received negative inflows in 2013, such as Finland and Switzerland. FDI to the
United Kingdom jumped to $72 billion, leaving it in its position as the largest
recipient country in Europe. Inflows to North America halved to $146 billion,
mostly due to an exceptional M&A divestment. The share of North America in
global FDI flows was reduced to 12 per cent (compared with 21 per cent in
2013). Inflows to the United States decreased to $92.4 billion, mainly due to
one large divestment (VodafoneVerizon). However, the United States remained the
largest host developed country. In Asia-Pacific, FDI flows to Australia and
Japan contracted, while those to New Zealand rebounded.
Outflows from European
countries were virtually unchanged at $316 billion, or 23 per cent of the
global total. Reflecting the highly volatile trends at the level of individual
economies, Germany almost trebled its outflows, becoming the largest direct
investor country in Europe in 2014. France also increased its outflows sharply,
to $43 billion. In contrast, FDI from other major investor countries in Europe
plummeted; FDI from the Netherlands (the largest European investor country in
2013) lost 28 per cent, and flows from Luxembourg (the second largest in 2013)
fell to a negative value. United Kingdom outflows fell to −$60 billion (largely
owing to the mirror effect of the Vodafone-Verizon divestment). In North
America, both Canada and the United States increased their outflows modestly.
FDI from Japan declined by 16 per cent, ending a threeyear run of expansion.
In May 2015, the
European Commission published a concept paper on “Investment in TTIP and beyond
– the path for reform”, the German Federal Ministry for Economic Affairs and
Energy published a suggestion for a model investment protection treaty for
developed countries, and Norway put forward a new draft model BIT for public
consultation.
The European Commission
proposed new approaches to key IIA provisions related to the right to regulate
and ISDS in its concept paper on “Investment in TTIP and beyond – the path for
reform”, launched in May 2015 (European Commission, 2015). Four areas are
identified for such further improvement: (i) the protection of the right to
regulate, (ii) the establishment and functioning of arbitral tribunals, (iii)
the review of ISDS decisions by an appellate body, and (iv) the relationship
between domestic judicial systems and ISDS. (European Commission, 2015[3]).
CONCLUSION
Foreign direct investment in the form of M&A help companies to overcome many limitations, such as access to finance, outdated technology, the
saturation / insufficiency of the domestic market, the slow adaptation to
changes in market conditions. Company
that acquires may be motivated by short-term goals to achieve profitability, and long-term strategic
objectives compared to the target economy. Relatively stable business conditions affecting the
long-term strategic orientation of the
company in achieving the long-term profitability, a table with long sides
can benefit both the acquirer and the target company and its national economy. Given
that very often goals in country's with transitional economy, characterized by
a number of macroeconomic problems that impede economic development and the
chronic lack of capital that is necessary to compensate for attracting foreign
investments make it considerably more complex.
[2] See also
Guimaraes, Figueirdo and Woodward (2003).
[3] European
Commission (2015). pp. 11–12. “Investment in TTIP and beyond – the path for
reform”, Concept Paper, May. http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2015/may/tradoc_153408.PDF (11.03.2016)
[FMZ1]the emergence of new
sources of investment capital have caused separation of ownership structures from management. The goal of the owners is to maximize capital investment with higher rate of ROI.
High degree of differences in goals leads
to a significant conflict of interest which
is defined as an agency problem.
No comments :
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.