Stakeholder Theory
Stakeholder
concept is emphasized by Brummer (1991), justifying the theory from the
perspective of descriptive, instrumental, and normative justifications. The
main question is “Why would anyone accept the stakeholder theory over
alternative conceptions of the corporation?” The conceptual model assume that
corporations whose managers adopt stakeholder principles and practices will
perform better financially than those that do not, summarizing in four central
theses.
Brummer
(1991) emphasized Stakeholder concept
Descriptive principal describe specific corporate characteristics and behaviors: the nature of
the firm, the way managers think about managing, how board members think about
the interests of corporate constituencies, and how some corporations are
actually managed. By the logic of descriptive justification, if new surveys
showed that managers were abandoning stakeholder orientations, or if the legal
support for broad stakeholder interests were to weaken, the theory would be
invalidated, and in general we can assume this like weaknesses. Critical point
of this approach is that descriptive support cannot be found in the literature,
it has limited significance and I can agree with author and with Pejovich
(1990:58) critics that the most important issues for stakeholder theory lie
elsewhere.
Proposition of instrumental principal is that corporations
practicing stakeholder management will, equal to relatively successful in
conventional performance terms like profitability, stability, growth, etc. Framework
model can be used for testing empirical claims, including instrumental
predictions, relevant to the stakeholder concept, considering like critical
point of view and weaknesses. Approach is
essentially hypothetical, it says, in effect, "If you want to achieve (avoid) results X, Y,
or Z, then adopt (don't adopt) principles and practices A, B, or C. By
Freeman (1984) and approval by Thompson (1967), stakeholders has arisen from a
tendency to adopt definitions such as "anything influencing or influenced
by" the firm. We can
ask the question: “Who are the legitimate stakeholders?”
The normative
approach include the identification of moral or philosophical
guidelines for the operation and management of corporations, in contrast to the instrumental principal, is not hypothetical but
categorical; it says, in effect, "Do (Don't do) this because it is the
right (wrong) thing to do. The argument is based on the
neoclassical economic theory that believes a company can do activities as long
as it is tranquil with the laws or the activities able to contribute to
shareholders maximization. Theory
support concept of a free market populated with free and rational preference
seekers, compatible with both stakeholder and no stakeholder perspectives. An Enterprise
strategy Schendel/Hofer (1979) describes the relationship between the firm and
society by answering the question “What do we stand for?”
We can conclude
that to justify the stakeholder model, conceptual apparatus of instrumental or
efficiency-based theories (i.e., principal-agent relations and "firm-as
contract" theory), rely upon no instrumental or normative arguments.
Some
future research questions:
• What is
the relationship between stakeholder management models and firm financial
performance?
The resource-based view perspective (RBV)
The RBV research on innovation is based on the
fundamental premise
that organizational resources and capabilities are those that underlie and
determine a firm’s capacity for innovation.
emergent strategy are the basis of
conceptual approach in the relationship between internal organization
capabilities and external environment opportunities (Barney (1991), Grant
(1991),. However, difference between them should be managed to gain competitive
advantage.
The
resource-based view perspective is the basis for environmental
responsibility. impact the financial
performance and the slack availability of resources are the vice versa (Cortez
& Cudia, 2012). Penrose
(1959), Barney
(1986) and Wernerfelt (1984)
suggested that firm’s
resources influences
the capability of a firm to expand its business, and that there is the positive relationship between
profitability and resources. Abnormal rents from resources can be earned
if the resources are valuable, rare, imperfectly imitable, and
nonsubstitutable. Valuable means that
the resources should enable the company to employ a value-creating strategy. Rare
refers to the scarcity of the resources. The more scarce of the resource
is the higher price reflected in the future. The proposed conceptual framework
of integration between resources and competitive advantage for a better firm’s
environment performance starting from the internal resources and environment,
driven by the awareness and motivation of sustainability. Fundamental question
of why firms are different and how firms achieve and sustain competitive
advantage by deploying their resources.
The RBV research on innovation is based on the
fundamental premise
that organizational resources and capabilities are those that underlie and
determine a firm’s capacity for innovation. Russo & Fouts
(1997) considered organizational resources trough perspective of physical assets and technologies, human resources and
organizational capabilities. Physical
assets can be a source of competitive advantage if an organization can utilize
them so that they “outperform” equivalent resources of competitors. Russo &
Fouts (1997) found evidence that the connection between environmental
performance and economic performance strengthens in higher-growth industries[1].
Slack availability is simply means that not all the
company resources are allocated to provide maximum wealth. basic theories of
slack availability of resources could be potential force for sustained
competitive advantage (Adkins, 2005).
Research-based view perspective suggests that
environmental cost, waste, and CO2 emissions have positive impacts
on financial performance. The latter was captured in several dimensions: sales,
cost of sales (which supposed to have a negative coefficient) and net income
are a proxy to capture profitability, ROA, ROE, and EPS are the basis for
stakeholder and shareholders intention, stock price as a future expectation of
company performance, and total assets as a representative of firm size.
On the other hand, previous researcher suggests the slack
availability of resources as an illustration of the reverse relationship. Here,
the financial performance has positive impacts on the environmental
responsibility. The argument based on the deem of companies have to be
profitable and have enough financial resources before engaging in environmental
responsibility. Thus, the variables should be reversed to capture this
relationship; Corporate Social Responsibility becomes the controllable variable
and financial performance as independent variable.
Dynamic capability deo RBV ili posebno
Dynamic capability
In organizational theory, dynamic
capability is the capability of an organization to
purposefully adapt an organization's resource base. The concept was defined by David
Teece, Gary Pisano and Amy Shuen, in their 1997 paper Dynamic
Capabilities and Strategic Management, as "the firm’s ability
to integrate, build, and reconfigure internal and external competences to
address rapidly changing environments."[1]
The term is often used in the plural form, dynamic
capabilities, emphasizing that the ability to react adequately and timely to
external changes requires a combination of multiple capabilities.
Teece et al., (1997) have put forward the so-called
‘dynamic capabilities’ framework. Dynamic capabilities refer to the firm’s ability to integrate,
build, and reconfigure internal and external competences to address rapidly
changing environments. In their view, coordination/integration, learning and
transformation are the fundamental dynamic capabilities that serve as the
mechanisms through which available stocks of resources (e.g. marketing,
financial and technological assets) can be combined and transformed to produce
new and innovative forms of competitive advantage.[2]
The Theory of the Growth of the Firm
The theory
of the firm consists of a
number of economic theories that
explain and predict the nature of the firm, company, or corporation, including
its existence, behavior, structure, and relationship to the market.[1]
Growth economics studies
factors that explain economic
growth – the increase in output per
capita of a
country over a long period of time. The same factors are used to explain
differences in the level of output per capita between countries, in particular why some
countries grow faster than others, and whether countries converge at the same rates of growth.
Much-studied factors include the rate of investment, population
growth, and technological change. These are represented in
theoretical and empirical forms (as in the neoclassical and endogenous growth
models) and in growth
accounting.[65]
Game theory is a branch of applied mathematics that considers strategic interactions between agents, one kind of uncertainty. It
provides a mathematical foundation of industrial organization,
discussed above, to model different types of firm behaviour, for example in an oligopolistic industry (few sellers), but equally
applicable to wage negotiations, bargaining, contract design, and any situation where
individual agents are few enough to have perceptible effects on each other. As
a method heavily used in behavioural economics, it
postulates that agents choose
strategies to maximize their payoffs, given the strategies of other agents with
at least partially conflicting interests.[47][48]
In this, it generalizes maximization approaches developed to
analyse market actors such as in the supply and demand model and allows for incomplete information
of actors. The field dates from the 1944 classic Theory
of Games and Economic Behavior by John von Neumann and Oskar Morgenstern. It has significant
applications seemingly outside of economics in such diverse subjects as
formulation of nuclear strategies, ethics, political science, and evolutionary biology.[49]
Risk aversion may stimulate activity that in
well-functioning markets smooths out risk and communicates information about
risk, as in markets for insurance, commodity futures contracts, and financial instruments.
Financial economics or simply finance describes the allocation of financial
resources. It also analyses the pricing of financial instruments, the financial structure of companies, the efficiency and fragility
of financial markets,[50] financial crises, and related government policy
or regulation.[51]
[1]
Session_4-2_RBV on Corporate Environmental Performance and Profitability
[2]
Kostopoulos,
Konstantinos C., Yiannis E. Spanos, and Gregory P. Prastacos. "The
resource-based view of the firm and innovation: identification of critical
linkages." The 2nd
European Academy of Management Conference. 2002.
[LUM1]Therefore, the hypotheses of this relationship in all the
three industries are as the following.
H1a : Corporate Social Responsibility positive
impact financial performance of automotive companies
H2a : Corporate Social Responsibility positive
impact financial performance of spare parts companies
H1c: Corporate Social Responsibility positive
impact financial performance of chemicals companies
[LUM2]Therefore, the hypotheses in the three industries are as
follows:
H2a: Financial performance positive impact
environmental responsibility of automotive companies
H2b: Financial performance positive impact
environmental responsibility of spare parts companies
H2c: Financial performance positive impact
environmental responsibility of chemicals companies
Those hypotheses can be expanded in each variable
corresponding to other variable.
[LUM3]Apart from avoiding future costs,
improving environmental preparedness and performance should lead to a
reputational benefit and increase the market value of a firm. With this in
mind, the following hypotheses were formulated and will be tested in
the coming analysis.
1) Model 1 – An increase in environmental preparedness rating
is positively correlated with ROA because the costs of preparedness are
assumed to be relatively low
2) Model 1 – An increase
in environmental performance rating is negatively correlated
with ROA because costs of performance are assumed to be
significant
3) Model 2 – An increase in environmental preparedness rating
is positively correlated with Tobin’s Q because environmental work in any form
is assumed to be a market value enhancing activity
4) Model 2 – An increase
in environmental performance rating is positively correlated
with Tobin’s Q because environmental work in any form is assumed to be a market
value enhancing activity
5) Model 3 – Costs of preparedness are assumed
to be relatively low even when being a first mover, therefore an improved preparedness rating
in already high‐rated companies is believed to be positively related to
ROA
6) Model 4 – An improved preparedness rating
even when the company is already high‐rated
is assumed to be positively related to Tobin’s Q since environmental work in
any form is assumed to be a market value enhancing activity
7) Model 5 – Costs
of performance are assumed to be significant, especially when
being a first mover, therefore an improved preparedness rating
in already high‐rated companies is
believed to be negatively related to ROA
8) Model 6 – An increase
in performance rating even when the company is already high‐rated is assumed to be positively related
to Tobin’s Q since environmental work in any form is assumed to be a market
value enhancing activity
Since the hypotheses proposed suggest that the results are interesting
only if they turn out in a particular direction, the one‐tailed t‐test is used to determine the level of
significance. (For more on t‐test, see appendix 1)
No comments :
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.