The influence of
financial incentives and other
socio-economic factors on electric vehicle adoption
William Sierzchulaa*, Sjoerd Bakkerb,
Kees Maatab, and Bert van Weea
Delft University of Technology
a
Faculty of Technology, Policy, and Management
b
Faculty of Architecture and the
Built Environment
Please do not cite or
distribute without author permission
*Corresponding author
w.s.sierzchula@tudelft.nl, +31-6-150-88735
Abstract
Electric vehicles represent an
innovation with the potential to lower greenhouse gas emissions and help
mitigate the causes of climate change. However, externalities including the
appropriability of knowledge and pollution abatement result in societal/economic
benefits that are not incorporated in electric vehicle prices. In order to
address resulting market failures, governments have employed a number of
policies. We seek to determine the relationship of one such policy instrument
(consumer financial incentives) to electric vehicle adoption. Based on existing
literature, we identified several additional socio-economic factors that are
expected to be influential in determining electric vehicle adoption rates
including: charging infrastructure, environmentalism, financial incentives,
fuel price, urban density, education level, per capita vehicles, number of
models available for purchase, local presence of electric vehicle production
facilities, introduction date, vehicle price, and electricity price. Using multiple
linear regression analysis, we examined the relationship between those
variables and 30 national electric vehicle market shares for the year 2012. The
model found financial incentives, charging infrastructure, and local presence
of production facilities to be significant and positively correlated to a
country’s electric vehicle market share. Results suggest that of those factors,
charging infrastructure was most strongly related to electric vehicle adoption.
However, descriptive analysis suggests that neither financial incentives nor
charging infrastructure ensure high electric vehicle adoption rates.
Keywords: Public policy, technology
adoption, electric vehicles, eco-innovation
1. Introduction
The IPCC (2012) noted that climate change caused by rising
levels of greenhouse gases (GHGs) poses a serious threat to the physical and
economic livelihoods of individuals around the globe and could negatively
affect ecosystems by putting 20-30% of plant and animal species at an
increasingly high risk of extinction.[1]
GHGs such as CO2 and N2O primarily come from the burning
of fossil fuels during activities including electricity production and
operating internal combustion engines. In 2010, the transport sector accounted
for 6.7 Gigatons of emitted CO2 or 22% of the world’s total (IEA,
2012a). Furthermore, global fuel demand for transportation is projected to grow
approximately 40% by 2035 (IEA, 2012b). The IPCC noted the need to reduce GHG
emissions (particularly in the energy and transport sectors) in order to avoid
a 2.4 – 6.4 degree centigrade increase in 2090 temperatures relative to those
from 1990 (IPCC, 2007).
Electric vehicles (EVs) are one possible innovation to help
address the environmental concerns identified above. However, EV adoption is
seen as being very limited without stimulation from external factors such as
stringent emissions regulations, rising fuel prices, or financial incentives
(Eppstein et al., 2011; Shafei et al., 2012; IEA, 2013). Of those factors,
consumer subsidies are specifically identified as being necessary for EVs to
reach a mass market (Hidrue et al., 2011; Eppstein et al., 2011). Part of the
reason that diffusion is expected to be so slow is that pollution abatement and
knowledge appropriability2 externalities reduce EV development and
consumer adoption, leading to an inefficient allocation of goods and services
known as a market failure (Rennings, 2000; Jaffe et al., 2005; Struben and
Sterman, 2008). In the case of EVs, market failures distort their prices
relative to ICEVs, which results in fewer electric automobiles being built by firms or bought by
consumers. Consequently, the potential to address climate change through EV
development and use is limited by externalities; neo-classical economics
indicates that government policy should be employed to help correct for such
situations (Rennings, 2000). Of these policy measures, demand side instruments
such as consumer subsidies are viewed as being particularly important during
the early commercialization period (IEA, 2013). However, based on previous
studies, there are reasons to question how effective such financial incentives
would be in encouraging EV adoption.
Firstly, the literature has presented conflicting results regarding
the effect of consumer subsidies on hybrid-electric vehicle (HEV) adoption.
While some studies have shown financial incentives to be positively correlated
to HEV sales (Beresteanu and Li, 2011; Gallagher and Muehlegger, 2011), Diamond
(2009) found that higher fuel prices, not consumer subsidies, were related to
increased adoption. In addition, Zhang et al. (2013) identified only a very
weak relationship between purchase subsidies and consumer willingness to buy
EVs. Thus, factors other than financial incentives could be the primary drivers
of EV adoption.
Secondly, due to the nature of radical innovation
development (Tushman and Anderson, 1986), there may be reasons to suspect that
consumers may not behave in the same fashion toward HEVs as they do toward EVs.
Innovations that are further away technologically from the dominant design are
associated with greater levels of uncertainty (Anderson and Tushman, 1990).
Consequently, since EVs represent a more radical technological departure from
ICEVs than do HEVs (Sierzchula et al., 2012), they result in increased levels
of uncertainty, specifically among consumers (Sovacool and Hirsh, 2009). This
uncertainty affects a broad array of industrial dynamics including future
profitability of a technology, government involvement, and willingness to pay
(Arrow, 1966; Nelson and Winter, 1977; Jaffe et al., 2005); the more an
innovation differs from the conventional technology, the less consumers are
willing to pay for it. Thus, higher consumer uncertainty regarding EVs
decreases the amount that individuals are willing to pay relative to HEVs, in
effect reducing the utility of financial incentives relative to EV adoption.
This makes it difficult to estimate the impacts of financial incentives on the
adoption of a radical innovation with significantly different performance
characteristics relative to the conventional technology, as is the case with
EVs. Therefore, earlier studies analyzing HEV adoption may underrepresent the
impact that financial incentives have on EV purchases.
In addition, consumer subsidies may have little effect on EV
sales uptake if buyers are uncomfortable with the technology (Egbue and Long,
2012), or do not see enough EVs in the fleet around them (a threshold effect)
(Eppstein et al., 2011). Our paper aims to contribute to the literature by
examining if and to what extent financial incentives and other socio-economic
factors explain EV adoption.
2. Barriers limiting innovation
The literature has identified several obstacles which limit
the diffusion of new technologies such as EVs. For example, knowledge spillover
applies broadly to all innovations while pollution abatement and bounded
rationality[2] are
typically associated with limiting the development and adoption of
environmental technologies (eco-innovations) (Jaffe et al., 2005; Rennings,
2000). These barriers, which limit EV diffusion by influencing both the
manufacturers that produce the automobiles and the consumers that buy them, are
described more comprehensively below.
2.1. General barriers
In studying the development of innovations, Arrow (1962)
determined that in a capitalist system, firms will underinvest in research and
development of new technologies. This is primarily due to uncertainty, but also
because an innovation’s public
benefit (for which businesses receive little financial compensation) often
outweighs its private value to the
company. The externality, of ‘positive knowledge spillover,’ occurs when
innovations provide valuable information to non-consumers (Horbach, 2008).
For example, firms are not always able to prevent
competitors from gaining from their R&D efforts. The degree to which a firm
is able to defend the profits of an innovation from competitor imitation is
referred to as its appropriability (Teece, 1986). Because it is not possible
for a firm to keep every element of a new technology secret, other companies
can gain by learning from and in some cases stealing the work of the original
innovating entity. Thus, due to knowledge spillovers, businesses are less
likely to invest in the development of innovations that are easily copied
(having low levels of appropriability) because they will not be able to reap
all of the rewards from a successful new technology (Teece, 1986). Positive knowledge spillover influences the
industrial landscape such that although firms do invest in the research and
development of new technologies, they do so at a lower level than would be
expected based on the financial benefits that innovations provide.
In addition, emerging technologies face further barriers
because they often compare poorly to existing dominant designs in important
criteria such as price and performance (Adner, 2002). For that reason, the
first individuals to adopt an emerging radical innovation are often willing to
pay a premium or cope with sub-par performance in order to have the latest
technology (Rogers, 1995). The larger proportion of the population known as
early/late majority adopters are much more risk adverse, and are not willing to
purchase an innovation so different from the dominant design (Rogers, 1995). It
is vital for radical technologies to attract a significant enough number of
early adopters to develop a viable market niche (Geels, 2002). Thereafter,
industrial forces such as learning by doing and scale economies can rapidly
lower costs and improve performance (Foster, 1986; Christensen, 1997). In order
for an innovation such as electric vehicles to have a significant environmental
impact, it needs to be widely adopted (and have dramatically lower emissions
levels compared to ICEVs). For that to happen, there must first be enough
demand within the EV niche market that manufacturers continue to develop and
sell the automobiles. Consequently, governments have employed financial
incentives to help attract early EV adopters.
2.2. Barriers that reduce eco-innovation
Eco-innovations differ from other new products and services
in that they provide a lower environmental impact than the conventional
technology (Rennings, 2000). Examples range from incremental improvements to
existing designs such as turbocharging in automobile engines to more radical
technologies, like solar cells and wind turbines. The distinct nature of
eco-innovations improves general social utility through lower pollution
abatement levels. However, this externality also creates market failure, and
ultimately limits their development and adoption (Jaffe et al., 2005).
Investments in eco-innovation are specifically
disincentivized because benefits from lower pollution levels are not included
in a product’s price. The externality pollution functions such that that even
though many societal members profit from eco-innovations through improved
health (however marginally), firms are not able to charge those individuals for
their gains. As a result, eco-innovations have lower adoption levels than if
societal benefits from decreased pollution were included in product costs
(Brown, 2001).
An additional barrier that has contributed to lower
eco-innovation diffusion is bounded rationality, which can influence consumer
valuation of a product’s purchase price, operating expenses, and lifetime cost.
Instead of using rational choices to maximize an individual’s utility,
individuals are aware of only a portion of the available options and thus act
on imperfect information (Nelson and Winter, 1982). Thus, in place of
calculating out the total cost of ownership of a product, consumers often rely
on heuristics or rules of thumb to guide their purchasing behavior (Jaffe and
Stavins, 1994; Schleich, 2009). This can lead an individual to place too much
emphasis on the purchase price and not accurately value operating expenses
(Levine et al., 1995). Because many eco-innovations have high purchase prices
and low operating expenses, they have often experienced slow diffusion rates
(Brown, 2001). Specifically regarding EVs, consumers looking to purchase
alternative fuel vehicles do not accurately incorporate fuel economy in their
vehicle purchase decisions, leading to irrational behavior (Turrentine and
Kurani, 2007).
3. Factors influencing EV adoption
Because EVs were introduced to the broader consumer market
only recently in 2010 (not including their temporary commercialization in the
1990s), there is little research that uses empirical data to analyze factors
which affect adoption rates. Thus, much of our knowledge about such
contributing elements comes from stated preference studies. However, because of
a phenomenon known as the ‘attitudeaction gap’, there is the concern that
information from consumer surveys may have little relation to the purchase of
low-emission vehicles (Lane and Potter, 2007). This raises the value of
research that analyzes actual consumer actions (revealed preferences), such as
that performed in our paper.
HEVs provide a good comparison basis for EVs (even though
they are less of a radical innovation) because they have several of the same
key elements including a battery and electric motor based powertrain and lower
environmental impacts. As HEVs have been commercially available since the late
1990s, there are several studies that used revealed preference data to
investigate factors that influenced consumer uptake for those automobiles. In
the absence of similar research for EVs, we have incorporated in our model
variables that were found to be significant drivers of HEV adoption in those
articles e.g., education level, fuel price, and environmentalism (Lane and
Potter, 2007; Diamond, 2009; Gallagher and Muehlegger, 2011). Based on the
findings in HEV revealed preference research, EV survey studies, and
theoretical articles, we have collected and categorized the factors that are
assumed to determine the decision of whether or not to purchase an electric
vehicle as belonging to the technology itself, the consumer, or the context.
The technology category comprises aspects of electric
vehicles including battery costs and performance characteristics (driving range
and charging time). EV purchase prices, which are heavily dependent on battery
costs, have been identified as being the most significant obstacle to
widespread EV diffusion (Brownstone et al., 2000). The IEA (2011) found that
the purchase price of an EV with a 30 kWh battery (approx. 85 miles[3] of driving
range at 0.17 kWh/mile) would be $10,000 (all financial amounts in this article
should be read as US dollars) more than a comparable ICEV. Battery costs also
have an impact on the driving range of an EV. An increase in the size of an
EV’s battery (in kWh) raises both its driving range and purchase cost.
Therefore, although consumers are sensitive to a limited driving range (Lieven
et al., 2011) that aspect must be balanced with its relation to vehicle battery
costs. An additional factor which influences consumer adoption is vehicle
charging time (Hidrue et al., 2011; Neubauer et al., 2012). Whereas most ICEVs
are able to refuel in roughly four minutes, EVs require ~30 minutes at a fast
charging station and up to several (>10) hours for charging from a 110 or 220 volt outlet, dependent on
battery size (Saxton, 2013). Relative to a comparable ICEV, an EV’s high
purchase price, limited driving range, and long charge period all have a
negative impact on adoption rate.
In addition to factors relating to the EV, consumer
characteristics also play a role in determining uptake. Studies have identified
levels of education, income, and environmentalism to all be positively
correlated to likelihood to purchase an EV (Hidrue et al., 2011) or HEV
(Gallagher and Muehlegger, 2011). However, these factors, specifically
environmentalism, are often less important to consumers than vehicle cost and
performance attributes such as those identified in the paragraph above (Lane
and Potter, 2007; Egbue and Long, 2012).
A third set of elements, which
the literature has found to influence adoption rates and is external to both
the vehicle and consumer, is categorized as context factors in our research. In
several studies, fuel
(gasoline or diesel) prices have been identified as one of
the most powerful predictors of HEV adoption (Diamond, 2009; Beresteanu and Li,
2011; Gallagher and Muehlegger, 2011), and have also been influential in
agent-based models forecasting EV diffusion (Epstein et al., 2011; Shafei et
al., 2012). Related to fuel prices, although less commonly incorporated in
analyses, are electricity costs. Those two factors combine to determine a
majority of EV operating expenses which in turn have an impact on adoption
rates (Zubaryeva et al., 2012; Dijk et al., 2013). Other studies have
identified availability of charging stations as an important determinant in consumer
acceptance of alternative fuel vehicles e.g., EVs (Yeh, 2007; Struben and
Sterman, 2008; Egbue and Long, 2012; Tran et al., 2012). A country’s level of
urban density could facilitate greater EV adoption as shorter average travel
distances might allow for wider use of the vehicles’ limited driving range
(IEA, 2011). Finally, there are several factors specific to EVs that could
influence adoption rates including vehicle diversity i.e. the number of models
that consumers can buy (Van den Bergh et al., 2006), local involvement i.e. the
presence of a local manufacturing plant (IEA, 2013), and public visibility i.e.
the number of years EVs have been available for purchase (Eppstein et al.,
2011).
4. Method
This section describes how EV adoption rates across a series
of countries were analyzed using a set of socio-economic variables. Section 4.1
describes the data that were collected. Section 4.2 outlines a more detailed
description of how financial incentives were operationalized. Section 4.3
provides the final model specification.
4.1 Data collection
We collected and analyzed data
from 30 countries for 2012. The year 2012 was selected as the study date
because important information such as charging infrastructure and EV adoption
rates were unavailable in earlier years. Our statistical analysis used data
from the following countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, China,
Croatia, the Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Greece,
Germany,
Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway,
Poland, Portugal, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, the United
Kingdom, and the United States. We selected these countries because of the
availability of data, specifically EV adoption and charging infrastructure
figures. In our study, we defined electric vehicles as including both pure
battery electric vehicles, e.g., Nissan LEAF, as well as plug-in hybrid
electric vehicles, e.g., Chevy Volt. As this definition of EVs was based around
vehicles with a plug, other HEV models such as the Toyota Prius were not
included in our analysis.
Based on the factors identified
in Section 3, we collected data for the following variables for each country in
our study: EV market share, financial incentives, urban density, education
level, an environmentalism indicator, fuel price, EV price, presence of
production facilities, per capita vehicles, model availability, introduction
date, charging infrastructure,[4] and
electricity price. EV adoption was operationalized as national market shares of
electric vehicles. Variable descriptions and their sources are provided in
Table 1. Notable absences include driving range and charging time. Those
variables were not added to our model because generally the same electric
vehicles were available for purchase in the countries in our sample. Thus,
there is no fundamental difference in the driving range of a Nissan LEAF in
China or a Nissan LEAF in Germany.6
<<Table 1: Description of variables and sources>>
4.2 Financial
incentives
To encourage EV adoption, countries have used financial
incentives from both technology specific policies, such as subsidies to EV
consumers, and technology neutral policies, such as emissions-based vehicle
taxes. These were applied either at the time of a vehicle’s registration or on
its annual circulation fee (license fees in the US). In some cases, countries
lowered automobile taxes for EVs, and in others they provided subsidies apart from
normal registration and circulation fees, thus presenting a very diverse
financial incentive landscape. This section of the study describes how such a
heterogeneous environment for subsidies was operationalized to allow for
analysis across countries.
In order to compare financial incentives that used different
emissions and monetary units, policies were standardized relative to CO2
emissions and 2012 US dollars. To
convert fuel use to CO2 emissions, we used the following formula: 1
liter/100km = 23.2 gram CO2/km (UNEP, 2012). We converted currencies
to US dollars using the averaged quarterly exchange rates from 2012. In some
situations, it was necessary to use a vehicle’s performance characteristics,
e.g., CO2 emissions[5] in order
to calculate the financial incentives of a particular policy. An example would
be an annual circulation fee in which the amount paid was dependent on a
vehicle’s CO2 emissions levels. However, this does not give an
indication of the savings relative to the purchase of an ICE vehicle (there is
no basis for comparison). In order to calculate the value of such financial
incentive policies, we used information from an ICEV and EV (a 2012 Volkswagen
Golf and Nissan Leaf respectively). Table 2 provides a description of the basic
characteristics of these vehicles.
<<Table 2: ICEV and EV used for policy valuation>>
Some policies, such as registration taxes, were applied on a
one-time basis. For other policies that required annual payments e.g.,
circulation fees, we sought to provide a more realistic notion of their
monetary value. We did this by using a 3 year payback period and consumer
discount rate of 30% (based on the work of Greene et al., 2005 and Yeh, 2007).
For example, a one-time registration subsidy of $1,000 maintains that value,
but an annual circulation subsidy of $50 provided a financial incentive of
$90.81 in our analysis.
For the countries studied in our sample, financial
incentives did not change considerably in 2011 and 2012. In absolute terms
during those two years, Portugal saw a $5,500 decrease in financial incentives
offered to EV adopters while Finland saw a $4,600 increase. Otherwise, national
financial incentive levels have remained constant over that time period.
4.3 OLS regression
The variables from Table 1 were
incorporated into an ordinary least squares (OLS) regression with a logit
transformation of the dependent variable to normalize distributions of EV
market share. This transformation is appropriate when data are skewed, or
bounded such as with a proportion (Lesaffre et al., 2007). A histogram of the
EV market share was skewed to the right, and the variable was a proportion.
After the logit transformation, a second histogram showed EV market share to be
normally distributed, validating this approach. The final model specification
is given as
+$%!&
where the subscript i
denotes the country, and ɛ is an
error term.
5. Results and discussion
This section includes a correlation matrix of variables used
in the model, a descriptive analysis of EVspecific factors, and results from
the statistical model identified above. Stress tests of the model were employed
to determine its general robustness and the relative impact of specific
variables. Finally, we discuss implications that arise from the results, which
provide a notion of how different policy measures such as fuel taxes, consumer
subsidies, and installing charging stations could influence EV adoption.
5.1 Correlation analysis of model variables
Looking at relationships between individual variables can
help to highlight dynamics that are not evident in linear regression models.
Appendix 1 provides a Pearson’s correlation coefficient and statistical
significance between the variables used in the base model specification. One of
the patterns that appears when analyzing this matrix is that many of the
EV-specific variables are strongly correlated (price, year of introduction,
availability, market share, financial incentives, and charging infrastructure),
indicating that industrial dynamics can become interwoven during the early
commercialization of a radical innovation. Another observation is that the EV
price variable has a negative correlation to a country’s market share.
Mitsubishi MiEVs were most expensive in countries where adoption rates were low
e.g., Turkey, China, and New Zealand, and they were cheaper in the US, Norway,
and Japan, countries with relatively high EV market shares. Sometimes this
difference was dramatic as with Australia ($53,126) and Switzerland ($26,925).
And while it is difficult to draw any conclusive results from such
correlations, they do provide a good basis for further analysis.
An additional correlation that was not included in Appendix
1 was between charging infrastructure and the type of EV (plug-in hybrid or
purely battery electric). Potentially, a country with a higher proportion of
plug-in hybrid-electric vehicles (PHEVs) would have less dependence on charging
stations, which could weaken the relationship between a country’s EV adoption
and its charging infrastructure. However, preliminary model estimations
identify that percent of PHEVs did not have a statistically significant
relationship to either charging infrastructure or EV market share. This
suggests that the proportion of a country’s EVs with an internal combustion
engine does not significantly relate to its charging infrastructure or adoption
rate.
5.2 Descriptive analysis of EV-specific
variables
In addition to socio-demographic factors such as income and
education level, our model also incorporated several EV-specific variables
including financial incentives, charging infrastructure, model availability,
and presence of a local manufacturing facility. The descriptive analysis of
these variables provided below identifies how significant correlations found in
Appendix 1 can actually involve a great deal of heterogeneity and diversity,
indicating the existence of other influential factors.
5.2.1 Financial incentives
Financial incentives and EV adoption in Figure 1 display a
positive and significant relationship (P-value of .01). Even so, there is
substantial variation among the data points. In addition, there appears to be
two groups of countries. The first is constituted by approximately the bottom
half of our study sample (14 countries) as represented by nations with
financial incentives less than $2,000. They exhibited lower EV market shares
with the exceptions of Sweden (.30%) and Switzerland (.23%), and to a lesser
extent Germany (.12%), and Canada (.13%). Consequently, 10 countries showed
little EV activity as measured by either financial incentives or EV
adoption.
<<Figure 1: Financial incentives by country and corresponding EV market share for 2012>>
The other group in Figure 1 is distinguished by the
countries with higher levels of financial incentives and greater variation in
their EV market shares. Some countries such as Norway and Estonia matched high
financial incentives with increased EV adoption. However, this relationship was
not uniform as other countries, including Denmark and Belgium, offered high
financial incentives but had relatively low levels of adoption. Figure 1
suggests that there are factors other than financial incentives that drive EV
adoption.
In addition to variables
captured by the model, there are likely to be country-specific factors that
influenced national EV market shares. For instance, consumers in Estonia
adopted 55 EVs in 2011 (mnt.ee, 2013), but the federal government decided to
purchase approximately 500 MiEVs in 2012
(Estonia, 2011). That single act largely explains why it
had such a high market share in 2012. Conversely, Norway installed extensive
charging infrastructure in 2009, and has experienced a more gradual increase in
EV adoption rates since 2010, predominantly through household consumers (SAGPA,
2012). An additional factor which is not captured by the financial incentive
variable is the subsidy's recipient. Through their purchase of a majority of EVs
through 2012, fleet managers were identified as being very important early
adopters (IEA, 2013). However Belgium's financial incentives were directed
specifically toward households, so they may have largely missed engaging the
fleet market, hurting the country’s adoption figures. These country specific
factors provide insight into factors not included in the model that had the
potential to greatly influence national EV adoption levels.
As identified in the methods section, countries employed
several different types of financial incentives based on the vehicle’s tonnage,
company car status, emissions, and powertrain, which can be broadly categorized
as either registration or circulation subsidies. Figure 2 below identifies how
countries approached financial incentives according those policy categories.
<<Figure 2: Breakdown of financial subsidies types offered by countries>>
Figure 2 notes that most available EV financial incentives
(78%) came in the form of registration as opposed to circulation subsidies. The
difference between the two is that registration funds were offered the year
that the EV was purchased while those based on a vehicle’s annual circulation
provided benefits over a multiple year time span. Perhaps one reason why
registration subsidies were the dominant form of financial incentives is due to
consumer high discount rates for circulation subsidies, effectively lowering
their perceived value. A correlation test between EV market share and
registration/circulation subsidies did not return a significant value
suggesting that it was the total financial incentive value and not the specific
policy type that was relevant for adoption rates.
5.2.2 Charging infrastructure
Figure 3 exhibits a positive and significant relationship
(P-value of .000) between charging stations (adjusted for population) and EV
adoption rates. Despite an overall
positive correlation, there were examples of wide discrepancies in the data as
evidenced by Estonia and Israel. Both countries had similar proportions of charging
stations, but Estonia had an EV adoption level 11 times higher than that of
Israel. There also appears to be seven countries with very low levels of both
charging stations and EV adoption.
<<Figure 3: National charging infrastructure by country and corresponding
EV market share for 2012>>
Not as much
information is available about national charging infrastructure as financial
incentives, perhaps because in many countries they are largely installed by
local municipalities (Bakker and Trip, 2013). Among the countries in our
sample, there have been several different approaches to building charging
infrastructure from federal mandate (Estonia) to auto manufacturer led (Japan)
to local government initiative (Belgium) to public-private partnerships (Norway)
(Estonia, 2013; SAGPA, 2012; ASBE, 2013; Nobil, 2012). This variety in approach
to charging infrastructure development likely relates to other factors that
influence EV adoption e.g., local involvement.
Analyzing Figures 1 and 3, five (out of the 30) countries
showed very little activity during the introductory phase of EVs, as measured
by financial incentives, adoption, or charging infrastructure installation.
Thus, countries in our study could be divided into two groups with divergent
attitudes toward EV adoption as reflected by government policy and consumer
purchase behavior. One set of countries seemed to be actively engaged in the EV
introductory market while the other appeared to show very little interest.
However, the discrepancy between the two groups will likely have little effect
on the overall success or failure of EVs as the countries invested in their
adoption represent a substantial majority of global GDP based on national
purchasing power parity (World Bank, 2013c).
5.2.3 Number of models available and local EV production
As identified in the correlation matrix, many of the
EV-specific variables displayed strong correlations. In order to better
understand how these factors interact, Figure 4 looks at three such variables: the
number of models available for purchase, whether a country produced EVs locally
(bolded columns), and adoption rates.
Figure 4: Number
of EV models available for purchase, production facilities, and national market
shares
In total, 45 different types of EVs were purchased in 2012
although a small number of models such as the Nissan Leaf, Chevy Volt/Opel
Ampera, and Toyota Plug-in Prius accounted for the lion's share (62%) of those
sales. The Mitsubishi MiEV was the most widely available, being adopted in 26
of the countries in our sample. There was a positive correlation between a
country's EV adoption rate and the number of models that were available for
purchase. In many instances, manufacturers sold a limited number of several
different EV models in their native country e.g., Ford in the US and Mercedes
in Germany. In those instances, manufacturers were likely experimenting with a
limited production of specific EV models before expanding their sales efforts.
Countries where native manufacturers heavily invested in EVs
e.g., Japan, France, and the US, had some of the highest EV market shares.
Other countries with EV production facilities but low adoption rates including
Germany and Italy did not have EVs made by native manufacturers broadly
available. This suggests a strong relationship between consumer adoption of EVs
and their being manufactured by native firms. Several of the larger countries
were much more prone to adopt native models, specifically China and Japan where
only EVs from native manufacturers were purchased. Of those two countries,
China stands out because very few EVs made by Chinese auto makers were sold
outside the country. Many manufacturers e.g., Ford, Audi and Mia Electric, were
nation-specific with sales only or primarily occurring in the country where
their production facilities were located.
The relationship between the variables in Figure 4 suggests a complex
relationship between consumers, manufacturers, and national attitude regarding
EVs.
5.3 OLS model results
and implications
Table 3 shows regression results from the 30 countries in
our study for 2012. We regressed the log of EV market share on financial
incentives, urban density, education level, an environmentalism indicator, fuel
price, EV price, the presence of production facilities, per capita vehicles,
model availability, introduction date, charging infrastructure, and electricity
price. We used graphical and numerical analyses to ensure that the data met
expectations of linearity, normality, and homoskedasticity. We used ANOVA tests
and histograms to test for linearity, Shapiro-Wilk tests for normality, and
visual analysis of scatter plots for heteroskedasticity.
<<Table 3: Regression results for 2012 electric vehicle adoption>>
The model’s adjusted R2 was 0.628 which means
that almost 2/3 of the variation in national EV market shares was explained by
the tested variables. The coefficients for financial incentives and charging
infrastructure were positive and statistically significant with P-values of
0.039 and 0.004 respectively. Of those two variables, charging infrastructure
had higher Beta values (both standardized and unstandardized), indicating that
it was stronger at estimating adoption levels. Thus, adding a charging station
(per 100,000 residents) had a greater impact on predicting EV market share than
did increasing financial incentives by $1,000. The presence of a local EV
manufacturing facility was also a significant variable, although to a lesser
extent with a P-value of 0.079.
From the information in Table
3, it is possible to extrapolate the relationship of both financial incentives
and charging infrastructure to EV market share. Holding all other factors
constant, each $1,000 increase in financial incentives would cause a country’s
EV market share to increase by .06 percent. For example, a country with an EV
market share of .22 percent that increased its financial incentives to
consumers by
$2,000 would see its adoption rate go up to .34 percent
(.22% + .06% + .06%). For charging infrastructure, holding all other factors
constant, each additional station per 100,000 residents that a country added
would increase its EV market share by .12 percent. This suggests that each
charging station (per 100,000 residents) could have twice the impact on a
country’s EV market share than $1,000 in consumer financial incentives, albeit
with different bearings on a nation’s budget.
However, as a note of caution, while our model did identify
that financial incentives and charging infrastructure were positively
correlated to national EV adoption levels, there is no guarantee that these
relationships hold for all countries, as evidenced in Figures 1 and 3. For
example, in Figure 1 Belgium and Denmark had very high financial incentives,
but relatively low rates of adoption. Conversely, Switzerland and Sweden
exhibited the opposite dynamic with low consumer subsidies but high EV uptake levels.
Figure 3 displayed the same sort of mixed relationship between charging
infrastructure and EV market share. Thus, financial incentives and charging
infrastructure should be seen as being likely but not certain to predict a
country’s EV adoption rate.
The empirical results provide a useful comparison with
stated preference surveys. While charging infrastructure and financial
incentives were (as expected) significant in predicting EV adoption, this was
not the case with broader socio-demographic variables e.g., income, education,
environmentalism, and urban density that the literature had anticipated to be
influential (Lane and Potter, 2007; Gallagher and Muehlegger, 2011; Egbue and
Long, 2012). In addition, despite its strong and positive correlation to HEV
adoption in earlier studies (Diamond, 2009; Beresteanu and Li, 2011; Gallagher
and Muehlegger, 2011), fuel price was not significant in predicting a country’s
EV market share. However, there are fundamental differences in those papers and
our study that could help explain these conflicting results. Firstly, the HEV
studies examined a single nation over several years whereas our study looked at
several countries for a single year. Secondly, fuel prices in those earlier
studies exhibited much greater variation than was found in our data.
Conversely, it could be that differences such as the complexity of total
ownership cost calculation and the role of charging infrastructure result in
fuel prices not having the same impact on EV purchases that they do with HEVs.
More research is necessary to identify the relationship between fuel price and
EV adoption, specifically studies that span multiple years and look at a single
country.
5.3.1 Sensitivity tests
In addition to econometric results found in Table 3, we also
performed several estimations to test the sensitivity of different variables
(specifically financial incentives and charging infrastructure) and the base
model’s overall robustness. These are described below in Tables 4 and 5 and are
referred to as Models 1-5 respectively. The individual variable(s) explored
through sensitivity analysis is identified below the Model’s number e.g.,
charging infrastructure in Model 1.
<<Table 4: Model sensitivity analyses 1 and 2>>
In Model 1, normalizing charging infrastructure for urban
density did not drastically affect results with the variables financial
incentives, production facilities, and charging infrastructure remaining
significant while the adjusted R2 (0.613) was also similar to that
of the base estimation. As such, the base model remains robust to this
sensitivity test. Model 2 explored the sensitivity of EV adoption to financial
incentives with different discount rates and payback periods. While the US
Energy Information National Energy Modeling System uses a 3 year payback period
and discount rate of 30%, other studies have found that consumers, specifically
businesses and government agencies, may more accurately calculate the total
lifetime costs of an innovation (Nesbitt and Sperling, 1998; Menanteau and
Lefebvre, 2000). As such, we ran a sensitivity test for a lower discount rate
(1.25%) and longer payback period (8 years, which is the warranty period for a
Nissan Leaf or Chevy Volt). This approach resulted in $25,000 more in available
financial incentives from $180,000 in the base model. This sensitivity test did
not substantially change the significant variables (financial incentives,
charging infrastructure, and EV manufacturer location) or the models adjusted R2,
(0.628) suggesting that differences in discount value and payback period have a
relatively weak influence on national EV adoption rates, although that could be
due to the small number of multi-year consumer subsidies i.e. those that
address circulation taxes.
<<Table 5:
Model sensitivity analyses 3 – 5>>Sensitivity analyses 3 – 5 show how the
model’s explanatory power changed with the removal of financial incentives and
charging infrastructure variables. Removing the financial incentives variable
in Model 3 resulted in the adjusted R2 decreasing from 0.623 in the
base analysis to 0.533. Taking out charging infrastructure in Model 4 caused a
more drastic reduction in adjusted R2 to 0.391. Removal of both
factors in Model 5 caused the model to lose most of its explanatory power; it
had no significant variables and an adjusted R2 of 0.238. From these
sensitivity tests this it is possible to conclude that in our model, charging
infrastructure was considerably stronger than financial incentives in
explaining EV adoption rates.
There were
several limitations in our models which had the potential to produce misleading
results. During the introduction of new technologies, there are often
discrepancies in supply among locales.
Differences in EV availability by locality may have contributed
to variation in national adoption numbers. In addition, our study analyzed
financial incentives from national governments. There are undoubtedly monetary
benefits, such as free parking or toll exemptions provided by regions and
cities that were not included in this study and were likely to have been
influential. The small number of observations per year is also cause for
caution when interpreting the results. Furthermore, by only studying one year,
the data does not allow for analysis of the relationship between important
variables e.g., financial incentives and charging infrastructure.
6. Conclusions
The purpose of this research was to explore the relationship
between financial incentives and other socio-economic factors to electric
vehicle adoption across several countries. We found that financial incentives,
the number of charging stations (corrected for population), and the presence of
a local EV manufacturing facility were positive and significant in predicting
EV adoption rates for the countries in our study. Of those variables, charging
infrastructure was the best predictor of a country’s EV market share. However,
descriptive analyses indicated how country-specific factors such as government
procurement plans or the target recipient of subsidies could dramatically
affect a nation’s adoption rate. On the whole this analysis provides tentative
endorsement of financial incentives and charging infrastructure as a way to
encourage EV adoption.
A second conclusion is that EV-specific factors were discovered
to be significant while broader sociodemographic variables such as income,
education level, and environmentalism were not good predictors of adoption
levels. This could be because national EV markets were so small relative to
overall automobile sales. Thus, while many EV consumers may have high levels of
education and be passionate about the environment, within the perspective of a
country such individuals still represent a tiny portion of the overall
population. Therefore, socio-demographic variables may not provide a good
indicator of adoption levels when comparing countries. If EVs emerge from a
niche market, then socio-demographic data might be more accurately used to
predict adoption levels at the national scale. Until then, EVspecific factors
such as amount of charging infrastructure, level of consumer financial
incentives, and number of locations that sell the automobiles are likely to be
more correct for estimating a country’s market share.
6.1 Policy implications
Based on our
results, a sensible policy approach for addressing EV market failures arising
from pollution abatement and knowledge spillover would be for governments to
provide consumer subsidies and/or increase their number of charging stations.
Due to the importance of consumer adoption during the commercial introduction
of a radical innovation (Nemet and Baker, 2009), such supportive measures could
make a wide difference in the level of EV diffusion in the coming decades. As
the charging station variable was the strongest predictor of EV adoption based
on Beta values stress tests, their installation may be more effective than
financial incentives. However, since these two factors are likely to be
complimentary, supporting both measures could be expected to lead to higher
market shares than focusing on either financial incentives or charging
infrastructure alone.
However, this study also provides three notes of caution to
countries that expect that they can achieve high EV adoption rates by
increasing their levels of financial incentives or charging infrastructure.
Firstly, the descriptive analysis identified several countries that displayed a
relatively weak relationship between the two factors and EV market share.
Secondly, it is possible that financial incentives or charging infrastructure
mask other dynamics which are significant in driving EV adoption. Consequently,
building policy only around those two factors may not support important
underlying elements. Thirdly, due to the constantly evolving environment during
the emergence of a radical innovation, industrial dynamics may change from year
to year. Therefore, while this study does show that financial incentives and
charging infrastructure are positively correlated to national EV market shares,
it is definitely not evidence of a causal relationship and should be treated
with prudence.
While national governments have been primarily responsible
for consumer financial incentives, installing charging points has largely been
left to local public bodies such as cities (IEA, 2013). However, the IEA (2013)
found that “infrastructure spending has been relatively sparse” (pg. 16), which
suggests that local and national levels of government should strengthen
coordination in order to better encourage EV adoption, supporting earlier research
by Bakker and Trip (2013).
Now that we have identified policies that could be effective
in encouraging EV adoption, a next question is whether they are actually
efficient in a societal and economical sense. To answer this question, an
elaborate ex-ante Cost Effectiveness Analysis (CEA) or Cost Benefit Analysis
(CBA) would be needed. However, given
the dynamic nature of radical innovations, one should be careful when applying
these methods to the EV case. That is to say, EVs may not significantly reduce
GHG emissions in the short term, but they have the potential to cause dramatic
decarbonization post 2020 (2012c), assuming a dramatic increase of the share of
renewables in the electricity mix. In that respect, financial incentives today
may be important for stimulating broader EV adoption in the future, and
consequently may provide benefits outside those typically included in a status
quo based CBA. Such additional benefits may be reason to implement these
policies even if the results from a traditional CBA were not very favorable.
Furthermore, it is difficult to compare the costs of
financial incentives for EVs with at least some competing policy options to
reduce CO2 emissions. Financial incentives to increase the sales of
EVs on a temporary basis may be needed in the early stages of EVs because they
cannot compete yet with internal combustion engine vehicles. If, in a few
decades, EVs would become a success, financial incentive policies could prove
to have contributed to this success. In other words, there may be a snowball
effect of current financial incentives which are fundamentally difficult to
grasp in a conventional CEA or CBA. We therefore suggest that these analyses
can be used to support decision making, but that their outcomes should be treated
with caution and that decision makers should always take a long term
perspective when interpreting these.
6.2 Suggestions for
future research
This study looked at a country’s total charging
infrastructure, not taking into account how a heterogeneous distribution of
charging stations (many in one city, few elsewhere) might influence EV
adoption. Specifically because of the important role played by local
municipalities in installing charging infrastructure, their allocation could
have an important affect on a country’s EV adoption rate (Bakker and Trip,
2013). Therefore, we suggest that future research focus on the relationship
between the distribution of charging infrastructure within a country and its EV
adoption rate.
In addition, our model found charging infrastructure and
financial incentives to be powerful predictors of EV adoption rates for the
countries in our sample. However, it is possible that the variables concealed
other important factors. Therefore, further analysis is necessary to unpack the
importance of charging infrastructure and financial incentives to determine
whether they are on their own good predictors of EV adoption, or if there are
other elements that also need to be present but were not included in our model.
For instance, fuel price volatility may provide insight into EV adoption that
is not captured through absolute fuel prices.
Acknowledgements
This paper is appreciative of the contributions Eric Molin
and James Dunn. Financial support was provided by the Netherlands Organization
for Scientific Research.
References
ACEA, 2012a. Overview of CO2 based motor vehicle taxes in
the EU. Brussels, Belgium.
ACEA, 2012b. Overview of tax incentives for electric
vehicles in the EU. Brussels, Belgium.
Adner, R., 2002. When are Technologies Disruptive? A
Demand-Based View of the Emergence of Competition. Strategic Management Journal
23, 667-688.
AID, 2013. AID Newsletter 1312, Europe’s 2012 electric car
sales end with a whimper. 4 February, 2013.
Anderson, P., and Tushman, M., 1990. Technological
Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change.
Administrative Science Quarterly 35, 604-633.
Arrow, K., 1962. The Economic Implications of Learning by
Doing. Review of Economic Studies 29(3), 155-73.
Arrow, K., 1966. Exposition of the theory of choice under
uncertainty. Synthese 16(3-4), 253-269.
ASBE, 2013. Charging locations. http://www.asbe.be/en/locations
[Accessed on 3-April-2013].
Bakker, S., Trip, J., 2013. Policy options to support the
adoption of electric vehicles in the urban environment. Transportation Research
Part D 25, 18-23.
Beise, M. and Rennings, K., 2005. Lead markets and
regulation: a framework for analyzing the international diffusion of
environmental innovations. Ecological Economics 52, 5-17.
Beresteanu,
A., and Li, S., 2011. Gasoline prices, government support, and the demand for
hybrid vehicles in the United States. International Economic Review 52(1),
161-182.
Brown, M., 2001. Market failures and barriers as a basis for
clean energy policies. Energy Policy 29, 1197-1207.
Brownstone, D., Bunch, D.S., and Train, K., 2000. Joint
mixed logit models of stated and revealed preferences for alternative-fuel
vehicles. Transportation Research Part B 34, 315-338.
CAAM, 2013. China auto sales up nearly 3%. http://www.caam.org.cn/
[Accessed 16-July-2013].
Caradvice, 2013. www.caradvice.com.au [Accessed 13-July-2013].
Chandra, A., Gulati, S., and Kandilkar, M., 2010. Green
drivers or free riders? An analysis of tax rebates for hybrid vehicles. Journal
of Environmental Economics and Management 60, 78-93.
Chargemap, 2013. http://chargemap.com [accessed on 3-April-2013].
Demographia, 2013. Demographia world urban areas 9th
annual edition.
Diamond, D., 2009. The impact of government incentives for
hybrid-electric vehicles: Evidence from US states. Energy Policy 37, 972-983.
Dijk, M., Orsato, R., and Kemp, R., 2013. The emergence of
an electric mobility trajectory. Energy Policy 52, 135-145.
Egbue, O., and Long, S., 2012. Barriers to widespread
adoption of electric vehicles: an analysis of consumer attitudes and
perceptions. Energy Policy 48, 717-729.
Eppstein, M., Grover, D., Marshall, J., and Rizzo, D., 2011.
An agent-based model to study market penetration of plug-in hybrid electric
vehicles. Energy Policy 39, 3789-3802.
Estonia, 2011. Estonia will promote the use of electric cars
under a Green Investment Scheme. Government communication unit, 03 March
2011.
Eurostat, 2013. Electricity households. http://www.energy.eu/#domestic
[Accessed 28-August-2013].
Gallagher, K., and Muehlegger, E., 2011. Giving green to get
green? Incentives and consumer adoption of hybrid vehicle technology. Journal
of Environmental Economics and Management 61(1), 1-15.Geels, F., 2002.
Technological transitions as evolutionary reconfiguration processes: a
multi-level perspective and a case-study. Research Policy 31 (8/9), 1257–1274.
Goodcarbadcar, 2013. Sales stats http://www.goodcarbadcar.net/p/sales-stats.html
[Accessed 13-July2013].
Greene, D., Patterson, P., Singh, M., and Li, J., 2005.
Feebates, rebates and gas-guzzler taxes: a study of incentives for increased
fuel economy. Energy Policy 33, 757-775.
Gronnbil,
2013 http://www.gronnbil.no
[Accessed 13-July-2013].
Hidrue, M., Parsons, G., Kempton, W., and Gardner, M., 2011.
Willingness to pay for electric vehicles and their attributes. Resource and
Energy Economics 33, 686-705.
Horbach, J., 2008. Determinants of environmental innovation
– New evidence from German panel data sources. Research Policy 37,163-173.
IEA, 2011. Technology Roadmap Electric and Plug-in Hybrid
Electric Vehicles. OECD/IEA, Paris.
IEA, 2012a. Key World Energy Statistics 2012. OECD/IEA,
Paris.
IEA, 2012b. World Energy Outlook 2012. OECD/IEA, Paris.
IEA, 2012c. Tracking Clean Energy Progress: Energy
Technology Perspectives 2012 excerpt as IEA input to the Clean Energy
Ministerial.
IEA, 2013. Global EV Outlook: Understanding the Electric
Vehicle Landscape to 2020. OECD/IEA, Paris.
IPCC, 2012. Renewable Energy Sources and Climate Change
Mitigation: Special Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.
Cambridge University Press. New York, NY.
Jaffe, A., Newell, R., and Stavins, R., 2005. A tale of two
market failures: Technology and environmental policy. Ecological Economics 54,
164-174.
Jaffe, A., and Stavins, R., 1994. The energy-efficiency gap:
what does it mean? Energy Policy 22, 804– 810.
JAMA, 2013. http://www.jama-english.jp/statistics/index.html [Accessed 13-July-2013].
Lemnet.org, 2013. http://lemnet.org [accessed on 3-April-2013].
Lesaffre, E., Rizopoulos, D., and Tsonaka, R., 2007. The
logistic transform for bounded outcome scores. Biostatistics 8(1), 72-85.
Levine, M., Koomey, J., McMahon, J., Sanstad, A., and Hirst,
E., 1995. Energy efficiency policy and market failures. Annual Review of Energy
and the Environment 20, 535-555.
Lieven, T., Muhlmeier, S., Henkel, S., and Walker, J., 2011.
Who will buy electric cars? An empirical study in Germany. Transportation
Research D 16 (3), 236–243.
Marklines, 2013. Statistics – sales database search. http://www.marklines.com/en/vehicle_sales/search_model
[Accessed on 15-December-2013].
Menanteau, P., and Lefebvre, H., 2000. Competing
technologies and the diffusion of innovations: the emergence of
energy-efficient lamps in the residential sector. Research Policy 29, 375-389.
Mnt.ee,
2013. 2012 Estonian vehicle registrations by motor type. www.mnt.ee [Accessed on
15December-2013].
Nelson, R., and Winter, S., 1977. In search of a useful
theory of innovation. Research Policy 6,
136-76.
Nelson, R. and Winter, S., 1982. An evolutionary theory of
economic change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Nemet, G., and Baker, E., 2009. Demand Subsidies versus
R&D: Comparing the Uncertain Impacts of Policy on a Pre-commercial
Low-carbon Energy Technology. The Energy Journal 30(4), 49-80.
Nesbitt, K., and Sperling, D., 1998. Myths Regarding Alternative
Fuel Vehicle Demand By Light-Duty Vehicle Fleets. Transportation Research Part
D 3(4) 259-269.
Neubauer, J., Brooker, A., and Wood, E., 2012. Sensitivity
of battery electric vehicle economics to drive patterns, vehicle range, and
charge strategies. Journal of Power Sources 209, 269-277.
Nobil, 2012. The Norwegian charging station database for
electromobility. Oslo, Norway.
OECD, 2010. Reducing transport greenhouse gas emissions.
Trends & Data: 2010. OECD/IEA, Paris.
Rennings, K., 2000. Redefining innovation – eco-innovation
research and the contribution from ecological economics. Ecological Economics
32, 319-332.
Reuters, 2012. TABLE – China retail gasoline, diesel prices
since 2003. http://af.reuters.com/article/energyOilNews/idAFL4E8D75DN20120207
[Accessed 10-7-2012].
Rogers, E., 1995. Diffusion of Innovations, 4th
Edition. New York, NY: The Free press.
SAGPA, 2012. Re-charged for success. The hird wave of
electric vehicle promotion in Japan. Östersund, Sweden.
Saxton, T., 2013. Understanding
electric vehicle charging. Plug in America.
http://www.pluginamerica.org/drivers-seat/understanding-electric-vehicle-charging
[Accessed 27August-2013].
Schleich, J., 2009. Barriers to energy efficiency: A
comparison across the German commercial and services sector. Ecological
Economics 68(7), 2150-2159.
Shafiei, E., Thorkelsson, H., Ásgeirsson, E., Davidsdottir,
B., Raberto, M., and Stefansson, H., 2012. An agent-based modeling approach to
predict the evolution of market share of electric vehicles: A case study from
Iceland. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 79(9), 1638-1653.
Sierzchula, W., Bakker, S., Maat, K., and van Wee, B., 2012.
Technological diversity of emerging ecoinnovations: a case study of the
automobile industry. Journal of Cleaner Production 37, 211-220.
Sovacool, B., and Hirsh, R., 2009. Beyond batteries: an
examination of the benefits and barriers to plugin hybrid electric vehicles
(PHEVs) and a vehicle-to-grid (V2G) transition. Energy Policy 37(3), 1095–1103.
Struben, J.,
and Sterman, J., 2008. Transition challenges for alternative fuel vehicle and
transportation systems. Environment and Planning B: Planning and Design 35,
1070-1097.
Teece, D., 1986. Profiting from Technological Innovation:
Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy.
Research Policy 15, 285-305.
Tushman, M., Anderson, P., 1986. Technological
discontinuities and organizational environments. Administrative Science
Quarterly 31, 439–465.
Turrentine, T., and Kurani, K., 2007. Car buyers and fuel
economy? Energy Policy 35, 1213-1223.
Tran, M., Baniester, D., Bishop, J., and McCulloch, M.,
2012. Realizing the electric-vehicle revolution. Nature climate change 2,
328-333.
UNEP, 2012. The European Union Automotive Fuel Economy
Policy. http://www.unep.org/transport/gfei/autotool/case_studies/europe/cs_eu_0.asp
[accessed 28-6-2012].
Van den Bergh, J., Faber, A., Idenbrug, A., and Oosterhuis,
F., 2006. Survival of the greenest: evolutionary economics and policies for
energy innovation. Environmental Sciences 3(1), 57-71.
World Bank, 2012a. Road sector gasoline fuel consumption (kt
of oil equivalent).
World Bank, 2012b. Road sector diesel fuel consumption (kt
of oil equivalent).
World bank, 2013a. GNI per capita (PPP).
World Bank, 2013b. Percent of labor force with tertiary
education.
World Bank, 2013c. GDP ranking, PPP based.
Yale, 2013. Environmental performance index 2012. http://epi.yale.edu/epi2012/rankings
[Accessed 11June-2013].
Yeh, S., 2007. An empirical analysis on the adoption of
alternative fuel vehicles: The case of natural gas vehicles. Energy Policy 35,
5865-5875.
Zhang, X., Wang, K., Hao, Y., Fan, J., and Wei, Y. 2013. The
impact of government policy on preference for NEVs: The evidence from China.
Energy Policy 61, 382-393.
Zubaryeva,
A., Thiel, C., Barbone, E., and Mercier, A., 2012. Assessing factors for the
identification of potential lead markets for electrified vehicles in Europe:
expert opinion elicitation. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 79,
1622-1637.
[1]
This is posed by the IPCC with ‘medium confidence’ under a situation where
global temperatures are 2-3°C above pre-industrial levels. 2 Knowledge appropriability or “knowledge
spillover” relates to the ability of a firm to benefit from technologies or expertise
that it develops as opposed to other companies gaining from those advances
without investing in the necessary R&D e.g., reverse engineering a
developed product. Knowledge spillover results in lower rates of innovation.
[2] The notion that an individual’s
decision making is influenced by the information that he/she has.
[3] 136 kilometers
[4]
Charging stations were identified such that there could be multiple stations at
a location, and multiple charging points (plugs) per station. 6 Differences in temperature would affect
driving range. With that in mind, the same vehicle in different countries might
have slightly different performance characteristics depending on weather
conditions. However, the precise effects of temperature on EV driving radii are
still being determined. For that reason driving range as influenced by
temperature was not included in our model, but could still contribute to
differences in adoption between countries such as Spain and Sweden.
[5]
For the policies analyzed in our study, CO2 emissions were
calculated from a vehicle’s tailpipe, based on standard driving cycles e.g.,
NEDC and FTP-75.
No comments :
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.