CORPORATE
GOVERNANCE:
EFFECTS ON
FIRM PERFORMANCE AND ECONOMIC GROWTH
Summry
This document
addresses corporate governance and its effect on corporate performance and
economic performance. It first recapitulates
and builds on previous work undertaken by DSTI, for example, it gives a more
explicit exposition of the shareholder and stakeholder models of corporate
governance. It then goes on to address
some of the underlying factors that promote efficient corporate governance, and
examines some of the strengths, weaknesses, and economic implications
associated with various corporate governance systems. In addition to providing data not presented
in the previous work, it also provides newly available information on ownership
concentration and voting rights in a number of OECD countries. The document also provides a survey of
empirical evidence on the link between corporate governance, firm performance
and economic growth. Finally, several policy implications are identified.
One of the most
striking differences between countries’ corporate governance systems is the
difference in the ownership and control of firms that exist across
countries. Systems of corporate
governance can be distinguished according to the degree of ownership and
control and the identity of controlling shareholders. While some systems are characterised by wide
dispersed ownership (outsider systems),
others tend to be characterised by concentrated ownership or control (insider systems). In outsider systems of corporate governance
(notably the US and UK) the basic conflict of interest is between strong
managers and widely-dispersed weak shareholders. In insider systems (notably Germany and
Japan), on the other hand, the basic conflict is between controlling
shareholders (or blockholders) and weak minority shareholders.
This document
shows how the corporate governance framework can impinge upon the development
of equity markets, R&D and innovative activity, entreprenuership, and the
development of an active SME sector, and thus impinge upon economic
growth. However, there is no single
model of corporate governance and each country has through time developed a
wide variety of mechanisms to overcome the agency problems arising from the
separation of ownership and control. The document looks at the various
mechanisms employed in different systems (e.g. concentrated ownership,
executive remuneration schemes, the market for takeovers, cross-shareholdings
amongst firms, etc.) and examines the evidence on whether or not they are
achieving what they were intended to do.
For example, one of the benefits of concentrated ownership is that it
brings more effective monitoring of management and helps overcome the agency
problems arising from the separation of ownership and control. Some of the costs, however, are low liquidity
and reduced possibilities for risk diversification. While dispersed ownership brings higher
liquidity it may not provide the right incentives to encourage long-term
relationships that are required for certain types of investment. Therefore, one of the challenges facing
policy makers is how to develop a good corporate governance framework which can
secure the benefits associated with controlling shareholders acting as direct
monitors, while at the same time ensuring that they do not impinge upon the
development of equity markets by expropriating excessive rents.
Introduction
At the 1998
Industry Ministerial, a new direction for industrial policy was stressed and
Ministers agreed on a number of priority areas for future work, including
corporate governance. The OECD Council,
meeting at Ministerial level in April 1998, also stressed the importance of
corporate governance and called upon the OECD to develop a set of corporate
governance standards and guidelines. In
order to fulfil this Ministerial mandate, the OECD established an Ad Hoc Task
Force on Corporate Governance, consisting of representatives from national
governments, other relevant international organisations and the private
sector. DSTI also participated in the
Secretariat team serving the Task Force and contributed substantive input into
the development of the OECD Principles on Corporate Governance, see OECD
(1999a). OECD Ministers, meeting in May
1999, endorsed the Principles developed by the Task Force and also agreed that
the Principles be assessed in due course, possibly in two years time. The OECD Council, therefore, also requested
continuing analytical work in this area, see OECD (1999b).
The May 1999
Council Ministerial also called upon the OECD to study the causes of growth
disparities (e.g. technological innovation, framework conditions for firm
creation and growth, SMEs, etc.), and identify the factors and policies which
could strengthen long-term growth performance. While macroeconomic factors
certainly play a major part in the economic performances of OECD countries,
governments have increasingly come to recognise that there are strong
complementarities between sound macroeconomic policies and sound microeconomic
foundations. As the last decade has seen
a convergence on what constitutes good macroeconomic policy the OECD countries
have increasingly come to recognise that weakness in microstructures can have
profound impacts on a macro level. For
example, the 1997 financial crisis in Asia was thought to be due, in part, to
weaknesses in the banking sector and in corporate governance. Countries are therefore looking towards
microeconomic foundations and structures in order to enhance their economic
performance. The OECD reports on
Regulatory Reform, the Jobs Study and the Principles for Corporate Governance
are good examples of this new approach.
This approach is also in line with the new direction of work for the
Industry Committee as set out by Industry Ministers at their 1998 OECD
Ministerial meeting.
One key element
of improving microeconomic efficiency is corporate governance. Corporate
governance affects the development and functioning of capital markets and
exerts a strong influence on resource allocation. It impacts upon the behaviour and performance
of firms, innovative activity, entrepreneurship, and the development of an
active SME sector. In an era of
increasing capital mobility and globalisation, corporate governance has become
an important framework condition affecting the industrial competitiveness of
OECD countries. Meanwhile, in transition
economies, privatisation has raised questions about the way in which private
enterprises should be governed. It is
thought that poor corporate governance mechanisms in these countries have
proved, in part, to be a major impediment to improving the competitiveness of
firms. Better corporate governance,
therefore, both within OECD and non-OECD countries should manifest itself in
enhanced corporate performance and can lead to higher economic growth.
However, there is
no single model of corporate governance.
Governance practices vary not only across countries but also across
firms and industry sectors. However, one
of the most striking differences between countries’ corporate governance
systems is in the ownership and control of firms that exist across countries. Systems of corporate governance can be distinguished
according to the degree of ownership and control and the identity of
controlling shareholders. While some
systems are characterised by wide dispersed ownership (outsider systems),
others tend to be characterised by concentrated ownership or control (insider
systems). In outsider systems of
corporate governance (notably the US and UK) the basic conflict of interest is
between strong managers and widely-dispersed weak shareholders. In insider systems (notably Continental
Europe and Japan), on the other hand, the basic conflict is between controlling
shareholders (or blockholders) and weak minority shareholders. However, these differences are also rooted in
variations in countries’ legal, regulatory, and institutional environments, as
well as historical and cultural factors.
Therefore, policies that promote the adoption of specific forms of
governance should attempt to account for the product and factor market
contexts, and other institutional factors, within which they are being
contemplated.
The OECD
Principles for Corporate Governance represent a common basis that OECD
Membercountries consider essential for the development of good governance
practice. This work, on the other hand,
provides an economic rationale for why corporate governance matters and
explores the relationship between corporate governance, corporate performance,
economic growth, and, where relevant, industry structure. The search for good corporate governance
practices in this context, therefore, is based on an identification of what
works in different countries and circumstances, to discern what lessons can be
derived from these experiences, and to examine the conditions for
transferability of these practices to other countries. Continued work in this area, therefore, will
aim to ascertain what are the key factors that shape the effectiveness of
different corporate governance mechanisms, and to determine what are the key
policy adjustments that are most needed in individual systems of corporate
governance. This analytical work will
also provide valuable input to the work of other Committees and Directorates,
especially DAFFE, and into OECD horizontal projects. In particular, it will provide input into the
assessment of the OECD Principles in due course and to the OECD mandate in
determining the underlying factors contributing to economic growth.
This paper
recapitulates and builds on previous work undertaken by DSTI, see OECD
(1998a).It also builds on lessons gleaned in the development of the OECD
Principles for Corporate Governance. It
structures the previous DSTI work better (e.g. it gives a more explicit
exposition of the shareholder and stakeholders models of corporate governance)
and goes on to provide a qualitative assessment of the strengths, weaknesses
and economic implications of different systems of corporate governance. In addition to new data on ownership
concentration and voting rights in a number of OECD countries, it also provides
data not presented in the previous work.
It also provides a survey of empirical evidence on the link between
corporate governance, firm performance and economic growth, identifying areas
in which a consensus view appears to have emerged in the literature. This work also examines areas not covered
previously e.g. the markets for corporate control, the effects of executive
remuneration, etc.
Section II of this paper provides an
analytical framework for understanding how corporate governance can affect
corporate performance and economic growth.
Section III looks at the critical differences in corporate governance
systems in OECD countries. It then goes
on to provide a qualitative assessment of the strengths, weaknesses, and
economic implications associated with the different systems. Section IV provides
a review of the empirical evidence of the effect of corporate governance on
corporate performance and economic performance, and section V concludes. Wherever possible, we also identify those
areas where policy implications emerge.
II. Analytical Framework: The Shareholder and Stakeholders Models of Governance
Corporate
governance has traditionally been associated with the “principal-agent” or
“agency” problem. A “principal-agent”
relationship arises when the person who owns a firm is not the same as the
person who manages or controls it. For
example, investors or financiers (principals) hire managers (agents) to run the
firm on their behalf. Investors need
managers’ specialised human capital to generate returns on their investments,
and managers may need the investors’ funds since they may not have enough
capital of their own to invest. In this
case there is a separation between the financing and the management of the
firm, i.e. there is a separation
between ownership and control, see Berle and Means (1932).
Before looking at
the relationship between corporate governance, firm performance, and economic
growth, it is useful to have a framework with which to understand how corporate
governance can affect firm behaviour and economic performance. One of the problems with the current debate
on corporate governance is that there are many different, and often
conflicting, views on the nature and purpose of the firm. This debate ranges from positive issues
concerning how institutions actually work, to normative issues concerning what
should be the firm’s purpose. Therefore,
in order to make sense of this debate, it is useful to consider the different
analytical backgrounds or approaches that are often employed.
The term
corporate governance has been used in many different ways and the boundaries of
the subject vary widely. In the
economics debate concerning the impact of corporate governance on performance,
there are basically two different models of the corporation, the shareholder
model and the stakeholder model. In its
narrowest sense (shareholder model), corporate governance often describes the
formal system of accountability of senior management to shareholders. In its widest sense (stakeholder model),
corporate governance can be used to describe the network of formal and informal
relations involving the corporation.
More recently, the stakeholder approach emphasises contributions by
stakeholders that can contribute to the long term performance of the firm and
shareholder value, and the shareholder approach also recognises that business
ethics and stakeholder relations can also have an impact on the reputation and
long term success of the corporation.
Therefore, the difference between these two models is not as stark as it
first seems, and it is instead a question of emphasis.
The lack of any consensus regarding the
definition of corporate governance is also reflected in the debate on
governance reform. This lack of
consensus leads to entirely different analyses of the problem and to the
strikingly different solutions offered by participants in the reform
process. Therefore, having a clear
understanding of the different models can provide insights and help us to
appreciate the different sides of this debate.
An understanding of the issues involved can also provide the basis from
which to identify good corporate governance practices and to provide policy
recommendations.
II.1 The Shareholder Model
According to the
shareholder model the objective of the firm is to maximise shareholder wealth
through allocative, productive and dynamic efficiency i.e. the objective of the
firm is to maximise profits. The criteria by which performance is judged in
this model can simply be taken as the market value (i.e. shareholder value) of
the firm. Therefore, managers and
directors have an implicit obligation to ensure that firms are run in the
interests of shareholders. The
underlying problem of corporate governance in this model stems from the
principal-agent relationship arising from the separation of beneficial
ownership and executive decision-making.
It is this separation that causes the firm’s behaviour to diverge from
the profitmaximising ideal. This happens
because the interests and objectives of the principal (the investors) and the
agent (the managers) differ when there is a separation of ownership and
control. Since the managers are not the
owners of the firm they do not bear the full costs, or reap the full benefits,
of their actions. Therefore, although investors are interested in maximising
shareholder value, managers may have other objectives such as maximising their
salaries, growth in market share, or an attachment to particular investment
projects, etc.
The principal-agent
problem is also an essential element of the “incomplete contracts” view of the
firm developed by Coase (1937), Jensen and Meckling (1976), Fama and Jensen
(1983a,b), Williamson (1975, 1985), Aghion and Bolton (1992), and Hart
(1995). This is because the
principal-agent problem would not arise if it were possible to write a
“complete contract”. In this case, the
investor and the manager would just sign a contract that specifies ex-ante what
the manager does with the funds, how the returns are divided up, etc. In other words, investors could use a
contract to perfectly align the interests and objectives of managers with their
own. However, complete contracts are
unfeasible, since it is impossible to foresee or describe all future
contingencies. This incompleteness of
contracts means that investors and managers will have to allocate “residual
control rights” in some way, where residual control rights are the rights to
make decisions in unforeseen circumstances or in circumstances not covered by
the contract. Therefore, as Hart (1995)
states: “Governance structures can be seen as a mechanism for making decisions
that have not been specified in the initial contract.”
So why don’t
investors just write a contract that gives them all the residual control rights
in the firm, i.e. owners get to
decide what to do in circumstances not covered by the contract? In principle this is not possible, since the
reason why owners hire managers in the first place is because they needed
managers’ specialised human capital to run the firm and to generate returns on
their investments. The “agency” problem,
therefore, is also an asymmetric information problem i.e. managers are better
informed regarding what are the best alternative uses for the investors’
funds. As a result, the manager ends up
with substantial residual control rights and discretion to allocate funds as he
chooses. There may be limits on this
discretion specified in the contract, but the fact is that managers do have
most of the residual control rights.[1] The fact that managers have most of the
control rights can lead to problems of management entrenchment and rent
extraction by managers. Much of
corporate governance, therefore, deals with the limits on managers’ discretion
and accountability i.e. as Demb and Neubauer (1992) state “corporate governance
is a question of performance accountability”.
One of the
economic consequences of the possibility of ex-post expropriation of rents (or
opportunistic behaviour) by managers is that it reduces the amount of resources
that investors are willing to put up ex-ante to finance the firm, see Grossman
and Hart (1986). This problem, more
generally known as the hold-up
problem has been widely discussed in the literature, see Williamson (1975,
1985) and Klein, Crawford and Alchian (1978).
A major consequence of opportunistic behaviour is that it leads to
socially inefficient levels of investment that, in turn, can have direct
implications for economic growth.
According to the shareholder model, therefore, corporate governance is
primarily concerned with finding ways to align the interests of managers with
those of investors, with ensuring the flow of external funds to firms and that
financiers get a return on their investment.
An effective
corporate governance framework can minimise the agency costs and hold-up
problems associated with the separation of ownership and control. There are broadly three types of mechanisms
that can be used to align the interests and objectives of managers with those
of shareholders and overcome problems of management entrenchment and
monitoring:
−
|
One
method attempts to induce managers to carry out efficient management by
directly aligning managers interests with those of shareholders e.g.
executive compensation plans, stock options, direct monitoring by boards,
etc.
|
−
|
Another
method involves the strengthening of shareholder’s rights so shareholders
have both a greater incentive and ability to monitor management. This approach enhances the rights of
investors through legal protection from expropriation by managers e.g. protection
and enforcement of shareholder rights, prohibitions against insider-dealing,
etc.
|
−
|
Another
method is to use indirect means of corporate control such as that provided by
capital
|
markets, managerial labour markets, and
markets for corporate control e.g. take-overs.
One of the
critiques of the shareholder model of the corporation is the implicit
presumption that the conflicts are between strong, entrenched managers and
weak, dispersed shareholders. This has
led to an almost exclusive focus, in both the analytical work and in reform
efforts, of resolving the monitoring and management entrenchment problems which
are the main corporate governance problems in the principal-agent context with
dispersed ownership. For example, most
of this work has addressed concerns related to the role of the board of
directors, stock options and executive remuneration, shareholder protection,
the role of institutional investors, management entrenchment and the
effectiveness of the market for take-overs, etc.
The fact is that
the widely held firm, presumed in Berle and Means (1932) seminal work, is not
the rule but is rather the exception.[2] Instead, the dominant organisational form for
the firm is one characterised by concentrated ownership. One of the reasons why we observe ownership
concentration may be due, in part, to the lack of investor protection. However, unlike the widely-held corporation
where managers have most of the residual control rights with shareholders
having very little power, the closelyheld corporation is usually controlled by
a majority shareholder or by a group of controlling blockholders. This could be
an individual or family, or blockholders such as financial institutions, or other
corporations acting through a holding company or cross shareholdings.
Another reason
why ownership concentration is so prevalent as the dominant organisational form
is because it is one way of resolving the monitoring problem. According to the principle-agent model, due
to the divergence of interests and objectives of managers and shareholders, one
would expect the separation of ownership and control to have damaging effects
on the performance of firms. Therefore,
one way of overcoming this problem is through direct shareholder monitoring via
concentrated ownership. The difficulty
with dispersed ownership is that the incentives to monitor management are
weak. Shareholders have an incentive to
“free-ride” in the hope that other shareholders will do the monitoring. This is because the benefits from monitoring
are shared with all shareholders, whereas, the full costs of monitoring are
incurred by those who monitor. These
free-rider problems do not arise with concentrated ownership, since the
majority shareholder captures most of the benefits associated with his
monitoring efforts.
Therefore, for
the closely held corporation the problem of corporate governance is not
primarilyabout general shareholder protection or monitoring issues. The problem instead is more one of
crossshareholdings, holding companies and pyramids, or other mechanisms that
dominant shareholders use to exercise control, often at the expense of minority
investors. It is the protection of
minority shareholders that becomes critical in this case. One of the issues that arises in this context
is how do policy makers develop reforms that do not disenfranchise majority
shareholders while at the same time protect the interests of minority
shareholders. In other words, how do we
develop reforms that retain the benefits of monitoring provided by concentrated
ownership yet at the same time encourage the flow of external funds to
corporations, and which, in turn, should lead to dilution of ownership
concentration.
Another critique of the shareholder
approach is that the analytical focus on how to solve the corporate governance
problem is too narrow. The shareholder approach to corporate governance is
primarily concerned with aligning the interests of managers and shareholders
and with ensuring the flow of external capital to firms. However, shareholders are not the only ones
who make investments in the corporation.
The competitiveness and ultimate success of a corporation is the result
of teamwork that embodies contributions from a range of different resource
providers including investors, employees, creditors, suppliers, distributors,
and customers. Corporate governance and
economic performance will be affected by the relationships among these various
stakeholders in the firm. According to
this line of argument, any assessment of the strengths, weaknesses, and
economic implications of different corporate governance frameworks needs a
broader analytical framework which includes the incentives and disincentives
faced by all stakeholders.
II.2 The Stakeholder Model
The stakeholder
model takes a broader view of the firm.
According to the traditional stakeholder model, the corporation is
responsible to a wider constituency of stakeholders other than shareholders.
Other stakeholders may include contractual partners such as employees,
suppliers, customers, creditors, and social constituents such as members of the
community in which the firm is located, environmental interests, local and
national governments, and society at large.
This view holds that corporations should be “socially responsible”
institutions, managed in the public interest.
According to this model performance is judged by a wider constituency
interested in employment, market share, and growth in trading relations with
suppliers and purchasers, as well as financial performance.[3]
The problem with
the traditional stakeholder model of the firm is that it is difficult, if not
impossible, to ensure that corporations fulfil these wider objectives. Blair (1995) states the arguments against this
point of view: “The idea [...] failed to give clear guidance to help managers
and directors set priorities and decide among competing socially beneficial
uses of corporate resources, and provided no obvious enforcement mechanisms to
ensure that corporations live up to their social obligations. As a result of these deficiencies, few
academics, policymakers, or other proponents of corporate governance reforms
still espouse this model.”[4]
However, given
the potential consequences of corporate governance for economic performance,
the notion that corporations have responsibilities to parties other than
shareholders merits consideration. What matters is the impact that various
stakeholders can have on the behaviour and performance of the firm and on
economic growth. Any assessment of the
implications of corporate governance on economic performance must consider the
incentives and disincentives faced by all participants who potentially
contribute to firm performance. With
this in mind, the stakeholder model has recently been redefined, where the
emphasis has been to more narrowly define what constitutes a stakeholder. Therefore, the “new” stakeholder model
specifically defines stakeholders to be those actors who have contributed
firmspecific assets, see Blair (1995).
This redefinition of the stakeholder model is also consistent with both
the transaction costs and incomplete contract theories of the firm in which the
firm can be viewed as a “nexus of contracts”, see Coase (1937), Williamson
(1975, 1985), Jensen and Meckling (1976), and Aoki, Gustafsson and Williamson
(1990).
The “best” firms
according to the “new” stakeholder model are ones with committed suppliers,
customers, and employees. This new
stakeholder approach is, therefore, a natural extension of the shareholder
model. For example, whenever
firm-specific investments need to be made, the performance of the firm will
depend upon contributions from various resource providers of human and physical
capital. It is often the case that the
competitiveness and ultimate success of the firm will be the result of teamwork
that embodies contributions from a range of different resource providers
including investors, employees, creditors, and suppliers. Therefore, it is in the interest of the
shareholders to take account of other stakeholders, and to promote the
development of long term relations, trust, and commitment amongst various
stakeholders (see Mayer, 1996).
Corporate governance in this context becomes a problem of finding
mechanisms that elicit firm specific investments on the part of various
stakeholders, and that encourage active co-operation amongst stakeholders in
creating wealth, jobs, and the sustainability of financially sound enterprises,
see the OECD Principles of Corporate Governance (OECD 1999a).
However,
opportunistic behaviour and hold-up problems
arise whenever contracts are incomplete and firm specific investments need to
be made. As discussed previously, one
consequence of opportunistic behaviour is that in general it leads to
underinvestment. The principal-agent
relationship discussed in the shareholder model is only one of the many areas
in which this occurs. Underinvestment in
the stakeholder model would include investments by employees, suppliers,
etc. For example, employees may be
unwilling to invest in firm specific human capital if they are unable to share
in the returns from their investment, but have to bear the opportunity costs
associated with making those investments.
Alternatively firms may be unwilling to expend resources in training
employees if once they have incurred the costs they are unable to reap the
benefits if employees, once endowed with increased human capital, choose to
leave the firm. Suppliers and distributors can also underinvest in
firm-specific investments such as customised components, distribution networks,
etc. In this broader context, corporate
governance becomes a problem of finding mechanisms that reduce the scope for
expropriation and opportunism, and lead to more efficient levels of investment
and resource allocation.
According to the
stakeholder model, corporate governance is primarily concerned with how
effective different governance systems are in promoting long term investment
and commitment amongst the various stakeholders, see Williamson (1985).[5] Kester (1992), for example, states that “the central
problem of governance is to devise specialised systems of incentives,
safeguards, and dispute resolution processes that will promote the continuity
of business relationships that are efficient in the presence of selfinterested
opportunism”. Blair (1995) also defines
corporate governance in this broader context and argues that corporate
governance should be regarded as the set of institutional arrangements for
governing the relationships among all of the stakeholders that contribute firm
specific assets.
One of the
critiques of the stakeholder model, or fears of participants in the reform
process, is that managers or directors may use “stakeholder” reasons to justify
poor company performance. The benefit of
the shareholder model is that it provides clear guidance in helping managers
set priorities and establishes a mechanism for measuring the efficiency of the
firms’ management team i.e. firm profitability. On the other hand, the benefit
of the stakeholder model is its emphasis on overcoming problems of
underinvestment associated with opportunistic behaviour and in encouraging
active co-operation amongst stakeholders to ensure the long-term profitability
of the corporation.
One of the most challenging tasks on the
reform agenda is how to develop corporate governance frameworks and mechanisms
that elicit the socially efficient levels of investment by all
stakeholders. The difficulty, however,
is to identify those frameworks and mechanisms which promote efficient levels
of investment, while at the same time maintaining the performance
accountability aspects provided by the shareholder model. At a minimum, this implies that mechanisms
that promote stakeholder investment and co-operation should be adopted in
conjunction with mechanisms aimed at preventing management entrenchment. Stakeholder objectives should not be used to
prevent clear guidance on how the firms’ objectives and priorities are
set. How the firm will attain those
objectives and how performance monitoring will be determined also need to be
clearly defined.
II.3 The Interaction of Corporate Governance with the Institutional and Economic Framework
There is another
argument, not addressed above, that asks why should we worry about corporate
governance in the first place, since product market competition should provide
incentives for firms to adopt the most efficient corporate governance
mechanisms. Firms that do not adopt
cost-minimising governance mechanisms would presumably be less efficient and in
the long run would be replaced, i.e. competition
should take care of governance. This
line of argument would oppose any external policy interventions on the grounds
that at best they are unhelpful and at worst distortionary. Rather than justifying public intervention,
it says that the resolution of governance problems should be left to market
participants. Thus recent development
in the managerial labour market, such as executive stock options and the market
for corporate control, e.g. leveraged and management buy-outs, are seen as
market responses to institutional deficiencies.[6]
While there are
likely to be important interactions between product markets and corporate
governance systems, market competition alone cannot solve the market failures
arising from asymmetric information, hold-up, and principal-agent problems that
are at the heart of the corporate governance problem. Market failures resulting in socially
inefficient outcomes are one of the strongest arguments in favour of policy
intervention. For example, product
market competition does not prevent managers from expropriating shareholders’
rents, with the consequential effect of producing sub-optimal levels of
investment. Therefore, solving this
problem requires more than encouraging product market competition.
However, we
should keep in mind that the effectiveness and form of different corporate
governance systems may be influenced by a number of factors, including product
market competition, the structure of capital and labour markets, and the
regulatory and legal environments. For
example, as Mayer (1996) states, where there is limited competition in capital
markets for the ownership of firms (i.e.
lack of an active take-over market), product market competition may be
especially needed to encourage good corporate performance. It has also been suggested, see Petersen and
Rajan (1995), that competition in financial markets makes it difficult for
firms to establish long-term relationships with financial institutions.
Shleifer and
Vishny (1997) argue that much of the differences in corporate governance
systems around the world stem from varying regulatory and legal
environments. They maintain that the
differences between corporate governance systems in OECD countries, while
important, are relatively small compared to the difference between these
countries and others. For example, in
less developed countries corporate governance mechanisms may be non-existent
and, where they do exist, are often particularly weak and ineffective. However, even in rich OECD countries,
corporate governance problems can still act as a major impediment to economic
growth. For example, Barca (1995) and
Pagano, Panetta, and Zingales (1995) claim that Italian corporate governance
mechanisms are so underdeveloped as to retard the flow of external capital to
firms. Therefore, understanding
corporate governance and its effects can guide policy discussions, not only on
the improvements in OECD countries’ corporate governance systems, but also
provide a basis for understanding the changes that may be required in other
countries where corporate governance systems are severely underdeveloped.
These interactions
between corporate governance, competition, and regulatory and legal
environments, leads to a systems approach to governance, see Aoki (1994). The drawback of a systemic approach to
corporate governance is that it is often difficult to formulate in any precise
way the interactions between different parts of an economy. However, whenever possible and feasible,
policies which promote specific forms of corporate governance should attempt to
account for the interactions between governance and other institutional
factors, e.g. the legal and
regulatory environment, the structure of product markets, and labour and
capital markets, etc. It is important,
therefore, that the governance of companies be considered in the context of the
overall properties and structure of economies.
III. Corporate Governance in OECD Countries:
Strengths, Weaknesses, and Economic Implications
One of the most
striking differences between countries corporate governance systems are the
contrasts in the ownership and control of firms that exist across countries. Corporate governance systems can be
distinguished according to the degree of ownership concentration and the
identity of controlling shareholders.
While some systems are characterised by wide dispersed ownership (outsider systems), others tend to be
characterised by concentrated ownership (insider
systems) where the controlling shareholder may be an individual, family
holding, bloc alliance, or financial institution and other corporations acting
through a holding company or via cross shareholdings. Therefore, two of the most basic conflicts
that can occur in corporate governance are the conflict between a controlling
manager and ‘outside’ widely dispersed shareholders, and the conflict between
‘inside’ controlling shareholders and outside minority shareholders, see
Shleifer and Vishny (1997) and Becht (1997).
While the interface between management and dispersed shareholders has
been an extensively studied aspect of corporate governance, the consequences of
the relationship between large controlling shareholders and weak minority
shareholders is less well understood.
However, it is this latter relationship that is the most common form of
corporate governance found in both OECD and non-OECD countries.
Table 1 below
gives some international comparisons of ownership concentrations across
countries.[7] Until recently, lack of hard data has been a
major impediment to research in this area.
The European Corporate Governance Network (ECGN) was founded in 1996 as
a vehicle for encouraging comparative empirical research on corporate
governance in Europe. For the European
countries, therefore, it was possible to get the most up-to-date information
available based on the recent work in this area by the ECGN.[8] Data for the US and Japan, on the other
hand, has had to rely on older studies and is the most recent available. As can be seen from the table the average
equity holding of the largest shareholder[9]varies
from 40% to 80% in most continental European countries whereas ownership
concentration is substantially lower in the UK, US, Japan, and the
Netherlands. Additional information on
ownership concentration is provided by Franks and Mayer (1995), who find that
in Germany and France, 80% of large publicly quoted companies have a single
shareholder that owns more than 25% of the stock, while in the United Kingdom,
the equivalent figure is 16%.
Furthermore, the authors find that in more than half of the largest
French and German firms there is a single majority shareholder i.e. a single
shareholder owns more than 50% of the stock; whereas the equivalent figure for
the UK is 6%.
Table
1. International Comparison of Ownership
Concentration
|
Year
|
Number of companies
|
Average
Largest Stake
(% of equity)
|
Austria
|
1996
|
600 largest
listed and unlisted non-financial companies
62 largest listed companies
|
82.2
52.4
|
Belgium
|
1995
|
135 listed companies
|
44.8
|
France
|
1996
|
282,322
companies listed and unlisted companies
680 listed companies only
|
66.2
57.9
|
Germany
|
1996
|
402 listed companies
|
55.9
|
Italy
|
1996
|
4173 listed
and unlisted manufacturing companies
214 listed companies only
|
61.1
48.0
|
Netherlands
|
1996
|
137 listed companies
|
26.9
45.3a
|
Spain
|
1995
|
394 listed companies
|
38.2
47.1b
|
United Kingdom
|
1992
|
189 listed companies
|
14.4
|
United States
|
1980
|
457 listed non-financial companies
|
25.4a
|
Japan
|
1984
|
143 mining and manufacturing companies
|
33.1a
|
Korea
|
1996
|
30 largest chaebols
|
44.1c
|
Source: Austria: Gugler et al.
(1999); Belgium: Becht et al. (1999); France: Bloch and Kremp (1999); Germany:
Becht and Bohmer (1999); Italy: Bianchi et al. (1999); Netherlands: de Jong et
al. (1999); Spain: Crespi-Cladera and Garcia-Cestona (1999); United Kingdom:
Goergen and Renneboog (1999); United States and Japan: Prowse (1994); Korea:
OECD (1998b) a Percentage of outstanding
shares owned by the largest five shareholders. b Percentage of outstanding
shares owned by the largest three shareholders.
c Share of ownership held by
the founding family and relatives plus those of other companies in the group.
However, in the
absence of one share - one vote, data on direct ownership concentration can
either under or overestimate actual control that shareholders exercise over the
corporation. This is because countries
have a variety of legal devices that can be used to separate ownership (i.e.
cash-flow rights) from control (i.e. voting) rights. Box 1 below provides a taxonomy of ownership
and voting power. Dispersed ownership
and dispersed voting power is associated with many small shareholders, the
absence of any large shareholders, and with one share - one vote. In this case, managers end up with
substantial residual control rights but takeovers are possible. However, it is also possible to have
dispersed ownership but concentrate voting power through the use of dual class
shares, golden shares, proxy votes and voting trusts, the issue of stock with
contingent voting rights triggered by control disputes, and pyramiding. This gives rise to a situation of strong
controlling blockholders and weak minority owners. Takeovers may be impossible in this
case. When ownership is concentrated and
voting rights are aligned with ownership rights, minority owners are again in a
very weak position. While similar to the
case where ownership is dispersed and voting power is concentrated, managers in
the latter case are also weak and the majority owners retain residual control
over the corporation. However, takeovers
are possible in this case since cash flow rights and voting rights are
aligned. Systems of corporate governance
found in OECD countries usually fall into one of these three categories.
It is also possible to have concentrated
ownership but dispersed voting power.
This can be accomplished through the use of voting caps (i.e.
restrictions on voting rights of large share positions) which can be used to
prevent large shareholders from exercising control. For example, although a shareholder may own
40% of the shares, there is a restriction that allows only 10% of the shares to
be voted. This effectively gives rise to
a situation of concentrated ownership but where the means for performing direct
monitoring are not available due to the dispersion in voting power. Therefore, although this type of system
affords some protection to minority shareholders from voting rights
restrictions, concentrated ownership but dispersed voting power has mainly
disadvantages from a corporate governance perspective. This is because not only does it insulate
management from effective direct monitoring by the owners, but it also protects
them from more indirect means such as hostile take-overs. For example, when cash-flow and control
incentives are misaligned there are few means of intervention available to
remove inefficient management i.e. take-overs are difficult, also resulting in
“strong managers and weak owners”. This system also results in low liquidity, low
diversification possibilities for investors, and a high cost of capital. Therefore this system has all the
consequential problems of monitoring found in outsider systems but none of its
advantages. While an individual firm
might chose this ownership structure, this governance structure is the
exception rather than the norm. For
these reasons, as a system of corporate governance, this structure is not
really observed in practice.
Box
1. Taxonomy of Ownership and Voting
Power
|
Dispersed
Voting Power
|
Concentrated
Voting Power
|
|
|
|
|
|
Dispersed
Ownership
|
Many small shareholders
|
Many small shareholders
|
|
|
|
||
|
One share/One vote
|
Voting power concentrated in the hands of
|
|
|
blockholders via dual class shares, golden
|
||
shares, proxy votes, voting trusts, etc.
|
|||
|
|||
Implications:
|
Implications:
|
||
“Strong Managers, Weak Owners”
|
“Strong Voting Blockholders, Weak
|
||
Takeovers are possible
|
Minority Owners”
|
||
Takeovers are impossible
|
|||
|
|
||
Concentrated
Ownership
|
Large shareholders
|
Large Shareholders
|
|
|
|
||
Voting power of ownership diluted via
|
Voting rights aligned with ownership rights
|
||
|
|||
capped voting
|
via one share/one vote, or concentrated
|
||
|
via separation devices.
|
||
|
|||
Implications:
|
Implications:
|
||
“Strong Managers, Weak Owners”
|
“Weak Managers, Weak Minority Owners,
|
||
Takeovers are difficult
|
Strong Majority Owners”
|
||
|
Takeovers are possible
|
||
|
Table 2 below provides a comparison of
voting power concentration in a number of OECD countries. As can be seen from the table, blockholdings
in Continental Europe are considerably higher than in the United States and
United Kingdom.[10] The median largest voting stake in listed
companies in most European countries is over 50%. This suggests that voting control by a large
blockholder is the rule rather than the exception in Europe. Furthermore, in no European country is the
median largest shareholder small enough to fall below the 5% disclosure
threshold. In addition, in the United
States over 50% of companies have a largest shareholder who holds less than 5%
of the shares, while there are virtually no such companies in Austria and
Germany.
Table 2. Comparison of Voting Power Concentration in
Listed Industrial Companies: Size of Largest Ultimate Voting Block (%)
|
Number of companies
|
Median largest voting block
|
Mean largest voting block
|
Austria
|
50
|
52.0
|
54.1
|
Belgium
|
121
BEL20
|
50.6
45.1
|
41.2
38.3
|
France
|
CAC40
|
20.0
|
29.4
|
Germany
|
374 DAX30
|
52.1
11.0
|
49.1
17.3
|
Italy
|
216
|
54.5
|
48.0
|
The Netherlands
|
137
|
43.5
|
42.3
|
Spain
|
193
|
34.2
|
40.1
|
United Kingdoma United States:
|
250
|
9.9
|
14.4
|
NYSE
NASDAQ
|
1309
2831
|
0b
0b
|
3.6
3.4
|
Source: Becht
and Roell (1999) and recent studies by
the ECGN can be found on http://ecgn.org a Random sample of 250 listed companies. b Below the 5% disclosure
threshold.
Not only do patterns of ownership
concentration and control differ dramatically across countries, but the
identity of owners also differs dramatically.
Some comparisons of the distribution of share ownership for a number of
OECD countries can be found below in table 3.
In outsider systems of corporate governance, typical of the US and UK,
ownership is primarily associated with institutional investors, however,
individual ownership is more prevalent in the US than in the UK. This is not true of insider systems, where
ownership is in the hands of either other corporations or controlling
investors, see Mayer (1996). For
example, in the rest of Europe, Japan, and Korea, cross-shareholdings amongst
firms are commonplace, relationships with banks are strong, and large family
holdings often dominate institutional investors.
Table
3. Ownership of common stock in selected
OECD countries Per Cent at year end
Financial Sector of which:
|
US
(1996)
|
Japan (1994)
|
Germany (1996)
|
France (1994)
|
UK
(1994)
|
Italy
(1994)
|
Sweden
(1996)
|
Australia2 (1996)
|
Korea (1996)
|
46
|
44
|
30
|
8
|
68
|
8
|
30
|
37
|
26
|
|
Banks &
other
Financial Institutions
|
7
|
281
|
10
|
4
|
10
|
5
|
1
|
4
|
12
|
Insurance Companies and Pension Funds
|
28
|
161
|
12
|
2
|
50
|
3
|
14
|
25
|
6
|
Investment funds
|
12
|
–
|
8
|
2
|
8
|
–
|
15
|
8
|
8
|
Non-financial
Sector of which:
|
54
|
56
|
70
|
92
|
32
|
92
|
70
|
63
|
74
|
Non-financial enterprises
|
–
|
24
|
42
|
58
|
1
|
25
|
11
|
11
|
21
|
Individuals
|
49
|
24
|
15
|
19
|
21
|
50
|
19
|
20
|
34
|
Public authorities
|
–
|
1
|
4
|
4
|
1
|
8
|
8
|
–
|
7
|
Foreign
|
5
|
7
|
9
|
11
|
9
|
9
|
32
|
32
|
12
|
Total
|
100
|
100
|
100
|
100
|
100
|
100
|
100
|
100
|
100
|
Note : Due to
rounding, the figures may not add up to the total.
Pension
funds in Japan are managed by trust banks and insurance companies. Division between banks and insurance
companiesare estimated. No data are
available on the extent to which mutual funds own shares. Securities houses do manage such funds.
These
companies are included under other financial institutions.
Australian
figures are for end September 1996.
Source : Japan: OECD (1996), Economic Surveys; France
and Italy: OECD (1997), Economic Surveys, France; Korea: OECD (1998b), Economic
Surveys; Australia: OECD (1998c), Economic Surveys; US, UK, German, and Sweden:
OECD (1998d), Financial Market
Trends,
no. 69
In addition to
differences in ownership concentration and the identity of owners across OECD
countries, significant regulatory differences also exist. Corporate governance is affected by the legal
and regulatory framework in which firms operate and vice versa i.e. there is a two-way causal
relationship between ownership structures and the legislative environment. For example, stock exchange regulations
regarding dual class-shares and takeover codes, which require firms to make
full tender offers once they have acquired a certain percentage of equity, can
impinge on ownership structure. In a
system with strong protection of shareholder rights the expropriation of
minority shareholders is limited.
Investors anticipating higher returns are ready to pay more for
shares. This, in turn, can induce
controlling shareholders to reduce their stakes or give up control, leading to
dispersed ownership. Hence, differences
in corporate governance systems around the world strongly reflect differences
in regulatory and legal environments.[11]
On the one hand,
although the legal and regulatory environment affects corporate governance, it
is also the case that legal rules and regulations are also, in part, the
outcome of different corporate governance systems. For example, systems with dispersed ownership
may have a stronger need for regulations that protect shareholder rights. For example, as ownership structure in the US
has become more dispersed, the legislative environment has adapted to the
particular needs arising from dispersed ownership. And many European countries are adapting
their legislative environments, in particular the strengthening of minority
shareholder protection, in response to abuses by controlling shareholders that
can arise in their systems of corporate governance.
Differences in countries’ systems of
corporate governance with respect to ownership concentration, the identity of
owners, and the regulatory and legislative framework, all have important
implications for both firm performance and economic performance. As noted above, the main agency problems in
outsider systems stem from the conflicts of interest between managers and
dispersed shareholders, while insider systems generally have large blockholders
who exercise control over management. In
the latter case, therefore, the main conflict of interest is between
controlling blockholders and weak minority shareholders. These differences are associated not only
with the degree of monitoring and control which owners exercise, but also with
differences in the degree of commitment and trust which exist amongst
stakeholders. For example, the identity
of owners can affect firm performance through the incentives they provide for
various stakeholders to make firm-specific investments. This in turn can impact upon the structure of
industry and underlying economic performance.
For example, ownership by other firms, cross shareholding, and
pyramiding can influence the behaviour of firms in product markets.[12]The
remainder of this section examines some of these potential channels of
influence and looks at the various strengths and weaknesses of outsider and
insider systems of corporate governance.
Section IV, on the other hand, examines the available empirical evidence
on the link between corporate governance and performance.
III.1 Outsider Systems of Corporate Governance
“Outsider”
systems, typical of the United States and the United Kingdom, are characterised
by relatively widely dispersed share ownership and high turnover. These systems tend to foster a more open and
equitable distribution of information and place a stronger emphasis on the
protection of shareholders rights and, in particular, those of minority
investors. Systems that protect minority
shareholders discourage active corporate governance since they give rise to an
absence of concentration of ownership.
Since strong minority shareholder protection is also associated with an
active stock market, the corporate governance frameworks in the US and UK are
designed to promote stock market activity.
For example, minority investors are normally afforded a high degree of
protection in securities law, and the requirements for disclosure tend to be
relatively stringent.
Regulation in
outsider systems has traditionally been structured to strike a balance between
providing adequate shareholder protection whilst, at the same time, allowing
investors to assume risks as they see fit.
This requires a framework that emphasises the need for reliable and
adequate information, so that investors are able to make informed investment
decisions. For example, regulation has
traditionally been structured to provide information to, and create relative
equality among, investors regarding access to information. For this purpose, disclosure requirements are
fairly stringent and there is a strong emphasis on the protection of
shareholder rights. For example,
elaborate rules prevent groups of shareholders from communicating and sharing
information among themselves without making the information available to all
shareholders. In addition, the legal
framework supports the rights of shareholders to control the company and in
many cases the board and management are explicitly accountable to
shareholders. Theoretically,
shareholders (through the use of their voting rights) have the power to select
members of the board and to vote upon key issues facing the company. In practice, however, the fragmentation of
ownership is a serious barrier to the actual exercising of such control.
The promotion of
financial markets is also important for sectoral development. Industry sectors that rely on external
funding are favored in outsider systems, where there is strong protection of
minority shareholders and more transparency.
Another important aspect of an active equity market is that this also
encourages innovative activity, entrepreneurship, and the development of a
dynamic small and mediumsized enterprise (SME) sector. For example, venture capital and business
angels are vital in supporting innovative activity and entrepreneurial talent,
and these are intimately linked with stock markets since this provides
investors with both an exit mechanism and liquidity. If we believe that active financial markets
are linked with economic development, then regulations that promote stock
market activity may provide one of the underlying sources for economic
growth. For example, the protection of
minority shareholders, which is linked to the development of stock markets, is
critical to promoting innovative activity, entrepreneurship, and the
development of sectors that rely on external funding.
The corporate
governance framework in outsider systems also favours the use of public capital
markets. The importance of equities and
corporate bonds as a source of long-term finance is an important feature of
outsider systems. Debt financing by
banks tends to be short term and banks tend to maintain arm’s length
relationships with the corporate sector.
For this reason, debt-equity ratios are relatively low. Capital markets
in outsider systems also play a much greater role in influencing the behaviour
of key parties. The monitoring of
management relies largely on the discipline of capital markets, which is
thought to serve as a particularly effective device for disciplining managerial
behaviour. For example, share prices are
likely to fall whenever management fails to maximise shareholder value,
exposing the company to the threat of a take-over bid and the removal of inefficient
management. However, liquid stock
markets, strict trading rules, and adequate disclosure of information (all
characteristics associated with outsider systems) are necessary in order for
the market for corporate control to act as effective disciplining device.
Some of the
advantages of dispersed ownership, therefore, include enhanced liquidity of
stocks and, consequently, better risk diversification possibilities for
investors. However, according to the
principal-agent model, one would expect the separation of ownership and control
to have damaging effects on the performance of firms. These difficulties are even greater when
ownership is dispersed. Not only do the
interests and objectives of managers and shareholders diverge, but the
incentives to monitor management are also particularly weak in this case. This is because the benefits from monitoring
are shared with all shareholders, whereas the full cost of monitoring are
incurred by those who monitor. Therefore, shareholders have an incentive to
“free ride” in the hope that other shareholders will do the monitoring on their
behalf. With dispersed ownership, “exit”
instead of “voice” are the consequences,[13]and
managers end up with considerable discretion and the possibility to extract
private benefits. For example, managers
may use their discretion to maximise firm size rather than profits; to hoard
cash flow rather than pay it out in the form of dividends; to pay themselves
excessive salaries; or to entrench and protect themselves from indirect means
of corporate control. Because of this,
outsider systems are often associated with a lack of managerial accountability.
An effective corporate governance framework
can limit the scope for managerial discretion.
Therefore, the corporate governance, legal,
and regulatory frameworks in outsider systems have developed in response to the
particular problems arising not only from the separation of ownership and
control, but also from the diffuse nature of share ownership. Many of the reforms or practices that have
arisen aim at addressing weaknesses in monitoring; at strengthening managerial
accountability; and at aligning the objectives of managers more closely with
those of shareholders. In addition to a
strong disclosure regime and an emphasis on shareholder rights, examples
include monitoring by institutional investors or pension funds,
well-functioning markets for corporate control, and executive remuneration and
compensation packages aimed at encouraging managers to maximise shareholder
value, etc.
III.1.1 The role of financial institutions
Share ownership
in the UK, and increasingly in the US, is characterised by the domination of
institutional investors (see table 3 above).
In the last forty years, both the US and the UK have seen a sharp rise
in the proportion of equity held by financial institutions, coupled with the
declining role of individuals in direct ownership. Rising from less than 10% of all equities in
the 1950’s to over 40% today, institutional investors have become the largest
owners of equity in both countries. Over
the same period, the proportion of shares directly held by individuals has
fallen from about 90% to around 50% in the US, and from about 50% to around 20%
in the UK.[14] The reasons for this trend can be attributed
to the tax incentives extended by governments to collective schemes and the
wide growth of mutual funds and unit trusts as a result of the advantages of
wider diversification, professional management, and lower execution costs
relative to direct share ownership. A further
factor explaining this phenomenon has been the increasing tendency for
companies to issue shares directly to institutional investors in the primary
market, as their funding requirements have risen in recent years.
The high degree
of share ownership held by financial institutions is a major factor in the way
corporate governance is exercised in the UK and US. Box 2 below provides an overview of the role
of financial institutions in the US corporate governance framework. Share ownership by institutional investors in
the UK is also highly concentrated. For
example, the top 25 institutional investors in the UK control more than 40% of
the value of shares held by all institutional investors. The largest shareholders of listed companies
are often the institutional investors and, as a consequence, many of the major
companies have broadly similar ownership profiles. The increased monitoring by institutional
investors is seen as an improvement in the way corporate governance is
exercised in the US and UK, since this is addressing one of the major
weaknesses of outsider systems. While in
the US competition in the market can to some extent provide a benchmark for
fund performance, there are still concerns as to who monitors the fund
managers. The high level of
concentration amongst institutional investors in the UK may only serve to
exacerbate this problem.
Box 2. The role of financial
institutions in corporate governance in the US
Unlike most of its leading competitors,
financial institutions in the US have long been
|
restricted by tougher legal and regulatory
constraints, resulting in a more fragmented
|
financial sector. As a result, commercial banks’ equity
holdings are especially low.
|
More than just restricting their share
ownership, legislation also hinders banks in their
|
client advisory capacity. For instance, where a client of a bank
becomes insolvent, the
|
legal doctrine of ‘equitable subordination’
downgrades the bank’s claim on the firm’s
|
assets if it can be shown that they exerted
a significant influence on the activities of the
|
firm.
Therefore, in comparison with other countries, commercial banks in the
US play
|
only a passive role in the monitoring of
listed companies.
|
Mutual funds have also become increasingly
significant and they now account for
|
approximately 12% of total stocks. However, their activities are also
restricted from a
|
corporate governance perspective, thus
limiting their effectiveness as institutional
|
monitors.
|
Of the different types of financial
institutions in the US, it is the pension funds that have
|
fostered the greatest upsurge in
institutional monitoring. Given the
use of indexing as an
|
investment strategy, public employee
retirement funds in the mid-1980’s realised that the
|
only alternative to further enhance fund
value entailed boosting corporate performance.
|
Therefore, institutions like CalPERS
(California Public Employees Retirements System)
|
have played an important role in removing
the former CEOs of IBM and General Motors.
|
However, owing to their closer commercial
ties, other pension funds such as employee
|
sponsored plans, have been less vociferous
on corporate governance issues.
|
The many constraints on institutions
holding large blocks of shares in individual
|
companies, as well as the legal protection
afforded to investors, has served to encourage
|
dispersed ownership. On the other hand, they have also served to
limit the significance of
|
concentrated ownership in the governance
process and to discourage long-term
|
relationships between financial
institutions and the corporate sector.
|
III.1.2 The role of the board of directors
In addition to the control exercised by
institutional investors, another relatively low-cost monitoring device can be
found in the board of directors. The
board plays a major role in the corporate governance framework. The board is mainly responsible for
monitoring managerial performance and achieving an adequate return for
shareholders, while preventing conflicts of interests and balancing competing
demands on the corporation. When
necessary, the board also has the authority to replace the management of the
corporation. For example, if management
is under-performing, then the board can replace the current management with
new, presumably more efficient, management that will maximise the firm’s
profits. The board is also responsible
for reviewing key executive and board remuneration. Box 3 below provides an example of some of
the recommendations that have arisen in the UK during the 1990’s regarding the
role of the board in corporate governance.
Box 3. The
role of the board in corporate governance in the UK
The Cadbury and Greenbury committees, set
up in the early 1990’s following a series of
|
high profile corporate scandals and
collapses, have been credited with being the driving
|
force behind many recent advances in the
corporate governance framework in the United
|
Kingdom.
|
In the UK, the board of directors tends to
be made up of an equal number of executive
|
and non-executive directors, the proportion
of non-executive directors increasing since
|
the recommendations of the Cadbury
committee in 1992. Non-executive
directors play a
|
key role in exercising control, and in this
regard the Cadbury code recommends a
|
minimum membership of three on each company
board. The proportion of companies
|
with combined Chairman and CEO roles, a
feature linked to a number of corporate
|
collapses, has also declined in the same
period.
|
The recommendations of the Cadbury and
Greenbury committees were also critical to the
|
widespread establishment of board
committees relating to the audit and strategy of the
|
corporation. Audit committees were proposed in order to
develop the monitoring role of
|
non-executive directors. The recommendations suggest that audit and
strategy
|
committees have a minimum membership of
three and exclude all executive directors.
|
These committees have been almost
universally adopted, although some smaller
|
companies have been slower to respond.
|
In order for boards to effectively fulfil
their monitoring role they must have some degree of independence from
management. While the emphasis in
outsider systems is on independence, in reality there is the very serious
problem that, like management, the board too can become entrenched. This is particularly the case when board
members are compensated for their activities, and are themselves responsible
for overseeing executive and board remuneration. And while there is a trade-off between
compensation that attracts high quality individuals as non-executive board
members, this also provides incentives to serve on a large number of
boards. This in turn can interfere with
performance, since service on too many boards reduces the monitoring ability of
board members. Even if regulations were
to limit the number of board positions that can be held, when you have
dispersed ownership, agency problems arising from the separation and ownership
and control still exist. Although the
board in theory should represent the interests of shareholders and the company,
in practice they often become part of the management of the corporation. Therefore, in outsider systems characterised
by weak owners, board members, like management, can easily become
entrenched. Because of these problems,
there is still a widely held perception of the board as a relatively weak
monitoring device.
III.1.3 The role of market mechanisms
The market for
corporate control is perhaps a much more effective disciplinary device than
either monitoring by institutional investors or by the board of directors. Capital markets in outsider systems play a
key role in influencing the behaviour of participants in the corporate
governance framework. As mentioned above, when then management of a firm is
inefficient or failing to maximise shareholder value, this exposes the company
to the threat of a take-over bid, with the consequential removal of inefficient
management. In the UK there has been an
average of over 200 mergers and acquisitions per year over the last decade,
compared with an average of about 50 in Germany. While up until now the market for corporate
control has not been a key feature of insider systems of corporate governance,
this is gradually beginning to change, as mergers and acquisition activity is
increasing and hostile takeovers are becoming more common. The US in particular has an active market for
corporate control as witnessed by its active market in mergers and
acquisitions, including a significant number of hostile take-overs. For example, in the mid-1980s alone, the
value of US mergers totalled approximately one trillion dollars, representing
40% of average annual market capitalisation.
However, the extent of hostile take-overs in the US may be somewhat
overstated, with only 172 successful bids between 1985 and 1989. Nevertheless, the mere threat of a take-over
may be enough to act as an effective disciplining mechanism and to diminish the
motivation for managerial opportunism.
The intensity of
the mergers and acquisitions market is not in and of itself evidence of a
powerful disciplinary device at work.
Take-overs can be prompted by rent seeking behaviour, empire building,
and tax minimisation, as much as from a desire to boost efficiency levels. Therefore, it is not always correct to assume
that a buoyant market for corporate control reflects the true extent of
corporate monitoring. Even if this were
not the case, it should not be forgotten that with legal, advisory, and
financing costs constituting on average 4% of the purchase price, this is a
particularly expensive way of aligning the interests of management with those
of shareholders. Nevertheless, the
mechanism is effective and should not be inhibited.
Product market competition can to some
extent act to reduce the scope for managerial inefficiency and
opportunism. This is because there are
fewer rents to be expropriated when markets are competitive. Competition also provides a benchmark by
which the performance of the firm can be judged when compared with the
performance of other firms in a similar sector.
However, the effects of product market competition are slow to act, forcing
inefficient companies into bankruptcy only after a long period of time has
elapsed, by which point most shareholder value has been eradicated. Therefore, bankruptcy legislation, by
influencing the claims and control of different investors in the event of
insolvency, also plays an important role in corporate governance.
III.1.4 Short-termist behaviour
While some of the
advantages of dispersed ownership include enhanced liquidity of stocks and
better risk diversification possibilities for investors, critics also argue
that the focus in this type of a system can be excessively short-term, reducing
overall investment to a level lower that is considered efficient. Although an
active market for corporate control can act as a disciplining device on
managerial behaviour, in an economy characterised by frequent take-overs,
long-term commitments between stakeholders may be more difficult to
sustain. Not only may this reduce
overall investment by providing weak incentives for stakeholders to provide
firm-specific investments, but it may also create biases in the type of
investment projects undertaken, and there are tradeoffs between short-run
benefits and long-run impacts on performance.
The heavy
reliance in outsider systems on financial markets may encourage managers to
focus excessively on projects with short term payoffs even when this is to the
detriment of long term corporate performance.
On the other hand, special financial devices have developed in outsider
systems (e.g. NASDAQ in specialised capital markets) which may be more
effective forms of risk financing for longterm R&D projects than
traditional intermediaries in many insider banking systems of corporate
governance. However, projects with
longer-term payoffs, such as basic research, may still be undervalued as a
result of stock market myopia. The lack
of an adequate measurement for intangible assets also favours applied or
targeted types of research at the expense of more exploratory research. On the other hand, more competitive markets
for finance and corporate control can lead to tighter monitoring of research
activities by company managers, with a more careful selection of projects and
strengthened cost control. This in turn
can lead to increased efficiency in applied research.
Overall,
increased competition in product and capital markets, while affecting the level
of R&D only marginally, has impacted on the pattern of R&D, shifting
research away from basic, exploratory research, towards more applied and
visible activities, see OECD (1998e).
This impacts upon innovation, technological development and long-term
economic growth since the purpose and contribution of basic research is to
increase the pool of knowledge required for applied research, which may be hurt
in the long run as a consequence.[15] For example, according to a survey of American
companies, the average length of research projects has decreased from 21.6
months in 1991 to 16.7 months in 1996 (R&D Magazine, 1997). A reduction in
government funding, which favours long-term research, also has the effect of
reinforcing market pressures towards more applied R&D.
The question,
therefore, is to what extent this shift toward applied research has occurred at
the expense of long-term growth potential, which depends primarily on science
and basic research. For example, this
shift results in a gradual weakening of potential technological opportunities,
eroding the basis for innovation, as well as the potential gains from
technology diffusion -- eventually hampering longterm economic growth and job
creation. While a shift in R&D
expenditures towards short-term, highpayoff projects may have the effect of
spurring higher productivity growth in the short to medium turn, any expansion
thus triggered should be of a transitory nature. Therefore, policy makers in systems of
corporate governance which tend to be more short-termist in nature, should pay
particular attention to the potential consequences of reducing government
funding for basic research. This is
further underpinned by the reported perception of firms that the exploratory
component of their research activities needs to be funded by government due to
a low private rate of return.[16]
By rejecting
projects in which returns fail to satisfy investor demand for more rapid
payoffs, it does not necessarily follow that managers are inefficient or guilty
of short-sightedness. Managers in this
case are merely following the dictates of the market. However, executive compensation plans geared
to align the interest of managers with those of shareholders may serve to
exacerbate short-termist behaviour. For instance, when managerial remuneration
is due largely to stocks or stock options, managers have an incentive to
maximise short-term results in order to increase their own compensation. Managers can maximise the total benefit to
themselves by engaging in projects that maximise short-term shareholder value
and then cash in on their stocks while moving to an executive position with
another corporation. At the same time
they benefit from the reputation effects of having increased shareholder value
in their previous firm of employment.
Therefore, while executive remuneration consisting largely of shares or
stock-options would seem to align the interests of managers with those of
shareholders, they may also create some of the wrong incentives. This would also seem to concur with the view
that executive pay packages in the UK and US are becoming excessive. This, in turn, has coincided with a move by
shareholders in these systems to limit executive remuneration, or at least to
have it more closely linked to corporate performance.
III.2 Insider Systems of Corporate Governance
“Insider” systems
typical of Europe (except UK), Japan and Korea, are characterised by
concentrated ownership or voting power and a multiplicity of inter-firm
relationships and corporate holdings.
This is very different from the structure of companies in the US and UK,
that are characterised by dispersed outside shareholdings (see tables 1, 2 and
3 above). Holding companies, banks,
other nonfinancial corporations, and familial control are dominant features of
insider systems. This includes close
relationships with banks, cross-shareholdings (both horizontal and vertical),
and pyramidal structures of corporate holdings.
The significance of a pyramidal structure is that it allows shareholders
at the top of the pyramid to exercise control in disproportion to their actual
holdings. Cross-shareholdings,
pyramiding, dual-class shares, proxy votes, and voting trusts can all help
shareholders extend their control at relatively low cost. Institutional investors such as pension
funds, mutual funds, and insurance companies also tend to play a much smaller
role in corporate governance than is the case in outsider systems.
The advantage of
concentrated ownership or concentrated voting power is that it can overcome the
problems with the monitoring of management that are associated with dispersed
ownership. This is because when cash
flow rights and control rights are aligned, majority shareholders now have both
the incentive and the power to monitor management. And with dispersed ownership but concentrated
voting power it is controlling blockholders who have an incentive to engage in
active monitoring. This is because, with
concentrated voting power (or ownership) controlling blockholders and majority
shareholders obtain a large fraction of the benefits from monitoring, and the
concentrated voting rights gives them the necessary power to influence the
decision making process. The basic
conflict, therefore, that arises with insider systems of corporate governance
is between controlling shareholders (or blockholders) and outside minority
shareholders i.e. “strong voting blockholders, weak minority owners” or “weak
managers, weak minority owners, strong majority owners”.
With dispersed
ownership but concentrated voting power, management entrenchment is also a
possibility, especially if the blockholders are managers themselves. Morck et.
al. (1988) define management entrenchment as the situation where a “manager
who controls a substantial fraction of the firm’s equity may have enough voting
power or influence to guarantee his employment with the firm at an attractive
salary.”[17] The possibility of management entrenchment is
one of the arguments often used in support of the one-share/one-vote principle. This is not to say that management
entrenchment does not arise in outsider systems. The weak monitoring incentives associated
with dispersed ownership can also lead to management entrenchment. But at least with one-share/one-vote
take-overs are possible, whereas with dispersed ownership and concentrated
voting power, take-overs become impossible.
Although
concentrated voting power has the advantage of increased monitoring, and in
principle increased firm performance, the controlling owner also has an incentive
to extract private benefits. Concentrated ownership or voting power raises the
possibility that large blockholders or majority shareholders collude with
management at the expense of small shareholders. One of the consequences of rent extraction by
controlling shareholders is that it raises the cost of equity capital as
minority shareholders demand a premium on shares issued. This problem may become particularly acute
when small investors do not have enough legal rights to secure a return on
their investment. In this case,
ownership concentration and voting power concentration can become detrimental,
since small investors avoid holding shares and the flow of external capital to
firms is severely impeded, see Shleifer and Vishny (1997), La Porta et. al. (1997), and Barca (1995).
The problem of
rent extraction is particularly severe in the case of small shareholders of
listed companies that belong to pyramidal structures e.g. holding
companies. When there is a difference
between cash flow rights and voting rights, the incentives for extracting
private benefits are much stronger and collusion between managers and
blockholders is more likely. While in
the US and UK managers should in principle maximise shareholder value, in
Continental Europe managers are often forced to maximise “blockholder value”,
and this does not necessarily maximise minority shareholders’ returns. In this case, minority owners can also be
expropriated though intra-group transfers by blockholders that control the
group. For example, blockholders may
have managers pursue objectives that are more profitable to them by diverting
resources to other companies owned by the blockholders, see Becht (1997) and
Barca (1997). Blockholders could also agree to vote favourably on management sponsored
proposals and be compensated by side payments.
These incentives arise because blockholders only bear a fraction of the
costs of these payments by foregoing the dividend payments associated with
their cash flow rights, but receive the full benefits associated with any side
payment.
One of the consequences of rent extraction
in insider systems is the lack of liquidity in secondary markets as investors
withhold funds, and a lack of opportunities for risk diversification as a
consequence of illiquid markets. Capital
markets in insider systems therefore tend to be much less well developed than
those found in outsider systems. On the
other hand, concentrated ownership not only increases the incentives for
monitoring, with presumably positive benefits for firm performance, but it also
encourages more long-term relationships and commitment amongst
stakeholders. This, in turn, can also
impact upon firm performance, increasing profitability in the long run. Therefore, although capital markets in
insider systems tend to be much less developed, the long-term nature of
relationships in insider systems provides incentives that encourage a greater
investment in firm-specific assets.
III.2.1 The role of banks in corporate governance
Long-term
relations with financial institutions can affect the performance of the
corporate sector. Differences in corporate governance systems are thought to
influence the cost of capital and the availability and type of financing
available to firms. For example, stock
market capitalisation as a percentage of GDP in insider systems is normally
lower than that found in outsider systems, see table 4 below. If the development of financial markets is
linked with economic development then this can impinge upon economic
growth. However, this may not matter if
there are other sources of financing available to the corporate sector. For
this reason, in insider systems there is a much greater emphasis on banks as
providers of external finance and debt/equity ratios are typically higher.
Unlike the arms
length relationships between banks and corporate clients found in outsider
systems, banks in insider systems tend to maintain more complex and longer term
relationships with the corporate sector, see box 4. In particular, the German and Japanese
systems of corporate governance are characterised by long-term relationships
with banks which are thought to encourage bank financing, whereas firms in the
US and UK benefit from high levels of equity capital. The benefits of a ‘bank-based’ system are
that banks perform important monitoring and screening functions. The close relationships between banks and
client firms in insider systems provides greater access to firm-specific
information, and is thought to be a factor contributing to lower risk premiums,
thus lowering the overall cost of capital faced by firms. For example, two of the principle assertions
as to the merits of ‘bank-based’ systems are that it reduces asymmetric information
problems enabling banks to supply more external finance to firms at a lower
cost, and thus increasing investment; and that it increases monitoring, thus
ensuring firms are run more efficiently.
Table 4. Market capitalisation of
listed domestic equity issues
As
per cent of GDP at year-end
Australia (Assoc. of SE)
|
1975
|
1980
|
1985
|
1990
|
1993
|
1994
|
1995
|
1996
|
22
|
40
|
37
|
37
|
71
|
67
|
70
|
80
|
|
Austria
|
3
|
3
|
7
|
17
|
16
|
16
|
14
|
15
|
Belgium
Canada
|
15
|
8
|
26
|
33
|
37
|
36
|
37
|
44
|
(Toronto and Vancouver)
|
30
|
45
|
45
|
43
|
61
|
59
|
66
|
86
|
Denmark
|
11
|
8
|
26
|
30
|
31
|
34
|
33
|
41
|
Finland
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
17
|
28
|
39
|
35
|
49
|
France
|
10
|
8
|
15
|
26
|
36
|
34
|
32
|
38
|
Germany (Assoc. of SE)
|
12
|
9
|
29
|
22
|
24
|
24
|
24
|
28
|
Greece
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
14
|
19
|
Ireland
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
40
|
49
|
Italy1
|
5
|
6
|
14
|
14
|
15
|
18
|
19
|
21
|
Japan
|
28
|
36
|
71
|
99
|
68
|
77
|
69
|
66
|
Korea
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
43
|
42
|
50
|
40
|
29
|
Mexico
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
16
|
50
|
31
|
32
|
32
|
Netherlands
|
21
|
17
|
47
|
42
|
58
|
67
|
72
|
95
|
New Zealand
|
–
|
–
|
39
|
20
|
56
|
53
|
53
|
56
|
Norway
|
–
|
–
|
16
|
23
|
24
|
30
|
30
|
36
|
Spain
|
32
|
8
|
12
|
23
|
25
|
25
|
27
|
33
|
Sweden
|
3
|
10
|
37
|
40
|
58
|
66
|
75
|
95
|
Switzerland2
|
30
|
42
|
91
|
69
|
114
|
109
|
129
|
136
|
Turkey
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
–
|
20
|
17
|
12
|
17
|
United
Kingdom
United States
|
37
|
38
|
77
|
87
|
122
|
114
|
122
|
142
|
(NYSE, Amex and Nasdaq)3
|
48
|
50
|
57
|
6
|
81
|
75
|
98
|
114
|
Italy – All
Italy on a net basis since 1985.
Switzerland –
only Zurich through 1990.
United States – including foreign shares in 1975.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Source: OECD(1998), Financial Market
Trends, February.
On the other hand,
the emergence and survival of new firms is strongly affected by the possibility
and cost of obtaining finance. In
insider systems, characterised by small and illiquid public capital markets and
the absence of venture capital markets, new firms and SMEs may find it very
difficult to obtain equity financing.
Therefore, the dominant financing pattern for firm start-ups and small
firms in insider systems implies a heavier reliance on debt financing than
found in outsider systems. This is a
serious problem for new firms, since they have no established track record or
long term relationship with the financial sector. Banks, in this case, tend to
be too conservative in their lending policies.
This is because banks face an asymmetric risk when assessing new
start-ups. For example, in the worst
case scenario the bank can lose all the credit it has extended to a new firm,
but should the venture succeed the best the bank can hope for is to be fully
repaid, including accrued interest. In
this way, the bank is excessively exposed to downside risk. Therefore, the absence of an active equity
market and a heavy reliance on debt financing, both characteristics of insider
systems, can impinge upon the development of a vibrant and thriving SME sector.
Box 4. The role of financial
institutions in insider systems of corporate governance
In many of the Continental European
countries, commercial banks play a leading role in the
|
governance of the corporate sector. Banks tends to be powerful, independent, and
mostly private
|
institutions. The universal banking system has also
enabled them to dominate all facets of financial
|
intermediation, which in turn has resulted
in capital markets remaining considerably less developed
|
than in outsider systems. Since information is often shared between
the bank and its corporate
|
client, bank based systems rely on
confidentiality. This runs counter to
the requirements of strong
|
public disclosure associated with outsider
systems.
|
The German system of corporate governance
is the classic example of a bank-based system. The
|
German tradition has been for each firm to
have a house bank that takes responsibility for most of
|
the financial transactions of the
company. The banks tend to hold
considerable equity portfolios
|
themselves, and are often seen as
representing all shareholders. In
addition, banks often name
|
representatives to the boards and exercise
considerable leadership and control in the company with
|
which they have a relationship.
|
Many insider systems are also characterised
by a pattern of interlocking share ownership among
|
groups of financial and non-financial
companies. In the Japanese context,
control is exerted
|
through keiretsu structures comprised of
groups of financial and industrial companies, including
|
suppliers and purchasers. A crucial feature of the Japanese system is
the emergence of banks as a
|
significant element of corporate
governance, where banks exercise their control over companies in
|
the group through a combination of
shareholding and lending activities.
Therefore, the main
|
external control over managers is by the
main bank, although this is rarely the largest stakeholder
|
in the company. The largest stakeholder usually being
another non-financial corporation.
|
In other countries, such as Korea,
ownership and control tends to be characterised by a small
|
number of ‘founding’ families of
entrepreneurs on the one hand, and a pervasive state on the other.
|
The government in the past has been able to
exert immense pressure on the banking sector and
|
direct much of their lending activities,
often on the basis of political connections rather than a
|
proper evaluation of risk. Coupled with a tendency for chaebol owners
to focus on growth at the
|
expense of overall profitability, this led
to inadequate risk assessment in the expansion and
|
diversification of chaebols. The prevalence of cross-shareholdings and
intra group debt guarantees
|
between group companies only served to
exacerbate this problem.
|
However, long-term
relationships with banks can also reduce biases that might favour investments
that generate short-term improvements in performance, see von Thadden
(1995). For example, a lower cost of
capital, by lowering the discount rate applied to the future stream of profits,
encourages more long-term investment.
This, in turn, can provide firms with a competitive advantage. The low
cost of funds is thought to have contributed to the relatively high level of domestic
investment that has been a strong feature of the Japanese economy in the
past. Therefore, long-term investments
without an immediate payoff, such as R&D and innovation, are more likely to
be undertaken in corporate governance systems that are based on long-term
relationships with financial institutions.
While banks in general may have a lower tolerance to risk than
shareholders, the close nature of the relationship tends to reduce asymmetric
information and risks associated with uncertainty. However, the overall effect of these opposing
influences makes it difficult to predict which system of corporate governance
is more likely to promote innovative activity.
The role of financial institutions in
financing failing companies is another important distinction between different
countries corporate governance systems.
Asymmetric information problems become particularly important in the
refinancing of failing firms. The
failure of creditors to be able to distinguish between firms with good or bad
prospects during periods of financial difficulties, can result in premature
liquidations.[18] Insider systems, with their closer
relationships between banks and the corporate sector, can mitigate some of
these information problems and may result in a more efficient allocation of
resources. Furthermore, competition in financial markets in outsider systems
may also undermine the development of long term relations between firms and
financial institutions. For example, the
willingness of banks to provide rescue finance for failing firms may hinge on
the expectation that these investments will yield long term returns. However, when there is competition in
financial markets and firms are free to shift to the lowest cost supplier of
finance once they are out of financial distress, then there is little incentive
for banks to provide rescue funds to the corporate sector. Banks in insider systems also play a much
more important role in the restructuring of poorly performing firms. Mayer (1996) states that restructuring of
poorly performing firms by Japanese banks is an important feature of the
country’s financial system; and that financial institutions (e.g. banks,
pension funds, and life assurance companies) in the US and UK often intervene
too late in corporate restructuring.
III.2.2 Long-term relationships: intra-group holdings
and commitment
The focus in
insider systems is much more on building long term relationships with many of
the contractual partners of the firm, thereby encouraging greater trust,
loyalty and commitment among the various stakeholders. It is thought that the continuous nature of
relations between these groups, including banks, the workforce, contractors and
clients, promotes a greater investment in firm-specific assets. Whereas,
outsider systems of widely dispersed ownership, where shareholders can walk
away from relations with other stakeholders without suffering any costs, makes
it difficult to sustain trust and commitment and do not provide the right
incentives to encourage firm-specific investment, see Mayer (1996).
The importance of
commitment and trust for firm performance can also vary by industry sector or
type of productive activity, see Williamson (1985), Mayer (1996) and Maher
(1997). For example Mayer (1996) states that they are “particularly important
where productive activity depends on the involvement of and investment by a
large number of stakeholders. Complex
manufacturing processes, which require several different supplier and purchaser
arrangements, may be particularly dependent on ownership patterns that promote
commitment and trust. Ownership patterns
are also relevant to activities that may require firm specific investments by
employees in training and acquisition of skills. Incentives to undertake such investments may
require commitments by employers to long-term employment and promotion policies
within the firm.”[19] Long-term relations and commitment are
therefore particularly important in high technology industries or activities
with high asset specificity. In these
industries it is the firm-specific investments made by various stakeholders,
rather than the flow of external funds, that impinges upon the performance of
the firm.[20]
Apart from the
concentration of ownership, the identity of owners can also have major economic
implications. Where ownership of a firm
is held by other corporations with which the firm has strong trading relations
e.g. suppliers or buyers, this provides incentives for firms to make
relationship-specific investment, see Williamson (1985). Ownership by one corporation in another
effectively reduces transaction costs and ‘hold-up’ problems associated with
incentives to engage in opportunistic behaviour. In this situation, economic
stakeholders, therefore, have a greater incentive to invest in
relationshipspecific investment. On the
other hand, complex patterns of ownership and large shareholdings can also
impede the restructuring of firms and industries, and diminish the adaptability
of firms to respond to changing circumstances and globalisation. The role of the Korean chaebols in connection
to the 1997 crisis in Asian markets provides one example amongst many, see OECD
(1999c).
One of the
problems with complex patterns of ownership and cross-shareholdings is that
insiders need not always own an outright majority of a company in order to maintain
control. For example, pyramid structures
allow dominant insiders to exercise control over a group with only a small
share of the total outstanding equity of the firm. Pyramids perform an important role in shaping
the corporate governance framework in Italy.
Widespread equity linkages in Italy have made it possible for around 150
core groups to exert control over almost 6500 firms.[21] In Italy these equity linkages tend to be
vertical and unidirectional i.e. at each level of the pyramid, firms own a control
stake in firms belonging to the immediately lower level. On the other hand, the controlling entity is
provided with a wide access to risk capital without jeopardising control. The potential liability of the controlling
shareholder/blockholder is limited. For
example, in the event of bankruptcy the controlling shareholder is only liable
for the indirect, often minority, stake held in the firm. Therefore, pyramidal groups by providing a
wide access to capital have some of the benefits associated with dispersed
ownership, while minimising the agency costs associated with the monitoring of
management. However, this type of group
structure is particularly prone to expropriation and a lack of transparency.
In contrast, in
Japan equity linkages are normally bi-directional. While unidirectional linkages ensure stable
control over all firms belonging to the pyramidal group, inter-group
cross-shareholdings on the other hand facilitate strategic alliances. Cross shareholdings, whereby corporations
with mutual business interests (or belonging to the same group) intentionally
hold each other’s shares, can be used to create a significant core of
insiders. In Japan, these cross holding
are concentrated among the keiretsu, made up of large corporations across a
wide range of industries, with banks at their centre. Large portions of stocks are held under this
type of an arrangement, often with the understanding that the shares will not
be sold without the understanding of the issuer. Through these linkages the strategic and
operational decisions of the firm are overseen by the holding company.
Complex patterns
of ownership, including both horizontal and vertical arrangements, serve to
protect both the group and lower level holdings from hostile take-overs. Long-term relationships between firms,
cemented by cross-shareholdings, may restrict the possibilities for a transfer
of share ownership. In addition, the
prevalence and stability of cross-shareholdings in insider systems, makes it
difficult to purchase a significant portion of shares in a company. As a result, the market for corporate control
in insider systems is likely to be less well developed than in outsider
systems. The available data suggests
that this is indeed the case. For
example, mergers and acquisitions activity in Japan is only marginal. In Germany hostile take-overs have been
virtually absent and in 1988, for example, take-overs were only half that level
of that found in the UK. However, this
is gradually changing and takeover activity, both in Japan and in continental
Europe, is on the increase, see OECD(1999b).
While on the increase, relative to the US and UK, takeover activity in
insider systems remains small in comparison.
Moreover, the
absence of an effective market for corporate control may also impede the
development of an international production base, and may prevent firms from
entering through domestic acquisitions.
In Germany, for example, the limited importance of listed joint-stock
companies, the role of cross-shareholdings between partner firms, and the
important role of employee representation on company boards, all make it very
difficult for outsiders to buy German firms.
At a time of globalisation this may be increasingly costly to firms.
While long term relationships between firms
and suppliers, and the subsequent sharing of information, can help promote efficiency
gains in terms of costs and quality, the subsequent increase in industry
concentration may weaken the overall level of competition in product
markets. The complex patterns of
cross-ownership that often arise between related companies in insider systems,
and which result in large corporate groups, can also result in collusive
behaviour, and has similar implications for competition policy. This suggests that insider systems of
corporate governance need to pay particular attention to strengthening product
market competition.
III.3 A Convergence in Systems?
The increasing
globalisation of capital markets and liberalising of international trade seem
to have created an environment in which differences in corporate governance are
becoming less severe. For example, while
family companies often predominate in Australia, Canada, and New Zealand, this
pattern of concentrated ownership coexists with a strong recognition of
shareholders rights, as well as the importance of greater transparency in the
corporate sector. And in outsider
systems there has been a growing appreciation of the powerful monitoring
incentives associated with concentrated ownership. Increasingly, institutional
investors and pension funds in the United Kingdom and United States are becoming
active participants in the corporate governance of firms in which they hold
substantial holdings. Venture capital markets and second tier markets such as
NASDAQ have also developed to accommodate outside financing towards closely
held firms.
Convergence
forces at work in both types of system are primarily a result of globalisation
of financial markets. There is also
growing evidence that firms are adopting corporate governance arrangements that
international investors appear to value.
Firms, and in particular large multinational firms, are increasingly
adopting the best practices of existing systems in an effort to improve
corporate efficiency and to attract external capital funds. In addition, the interests of international
investors, coupled with the capital requirements of major firms expanding
abroad, has led to a number of firms seeking a listing on foreign stock
exchanges. This change in the method of
financing is having a major impact on corporate governance. Raising capital though foreign stock
exchanges, where shareholders are more concerned about firm risks, is very
different from a bank-based system, where the banks are more interested in the
risk of default. Therefore, in many
insider systems of corporate governance, the increasing importance of foreign
investors as a source of capital for listed companies, is raising the demand
for more transparency and minority shareholder protection.
The agency
problems that arise from the separation of ownership and control raises the
need for a corporate governance framework which strengthens managerial
accountability and encourages managers to maximise profits, rather than pursue
their own objectives. In addition, a
good corporate governance framework needs to protect minority shareholders from
rent extraction by either managers or controlling shareholders while at the
same time encouraging efficient investment by stakeholders. The means by which this is attained varies
widely across countries and, even within a single country, across industrial
sectors. Each country has through time
developed a wide variety of capital market mechanisms and financing
arrangements, legal and regulatory frameworks, and other mechanisms to address
these agency problems. This is
exemplified by the current divergence in corporate governance structures found
in OECD countries.
The full implications
of recent developments are hard to predict, but there appears to be an overall
trend towards a degree of convergence in governance and financing patterns,
with outsider systems adopting some of the features of insider systems, and
vice versa. However, the extent of the
divergences between systems, which are historically contingent and rooted in
cultural, historical and legal differences, suggests that complete convergence
is unlikely. Furthermore, these
different systems of corporate governance are converging from different
directions. Therefore, the instruments
through which improvements will be attained, and the policy actions that are
called for, are also different.
IV. Corporate Governance and Performance: The Empirical Evidence
The previous
section showed that the patterns of ownership and control and, thus, the
systems of corporate governance varied considerably amongst OECD
countries. Ultimately, what is important
is whether or not these different corporate governance arrangements and, in
particular, differences in ownership and control affect corporate performance
or economic growth. If at the end of the
day, corporate governance has no impact on performance, then it is not clear
why policy makers should concern themselves with this topic. However, both the analytical framework in
section II and the discussion in section III above, showed that there are a
number of potential channels of influence through which governance can affect
performance. For example, these
differences are associated not only with the degree of monitoring and control
which owners exercise, but also with the incentives they provide for
investment, innovation, and entrepreneurial activity. As this section will show, the available
empirical evidence also suggests that corporate governance does affect
performance and is thus an important framework condition for the industrial
competitiveness of OECD countries.
The remainder of this section will
summarise some of the empirical findings regarding the impact of corporate
governance on performance. In
particular, it will look at the effects of different types of ownership
structure on firm performance. In
addition, it will examine the available evidence regarding the conflicts that
arise between different types of shareholders and, in particular, the possible
detrimental effects of dominant shareholders.
Other questions this section addresses include what is the available
evidence on entrenchment or rent extraction on the part of management, and does
the existence of an active take-over market actually work as a mechanism to
correct managerial inefficiencies and affect performance? It will also examine the available evidence
on whether or not executive compensation packages are effective in aligning the
interest of managers with those of shareholders and, thereby, increase firm
performance.
IV.1 Ownership concentration and firm performance
The ownership and
control of firms are pronounced and vary dramatically across OECD
countries. Therefore, one of the questions
that arises when considering whether or not corporate governance affects
performance includes whether or not owner-controlled firms are more profitable
that manager-controlled firms? A priori
it is not clear whether or not concentrated ownership and control will improve
performance. On the one hand,
concentrated ownership by providing better monitoring incentives should lead to
better performance. On the other hand,
it might also lead to the extraction of private benefits by controlling
blockholders at the expense of minority shareholders. These issues are central to the debate
surrounding corporate governance practices, particularly since concentrated
holdings are the primary means of control in so many countries around the
world.
Therefore, one question
to ask is whether or not the agency problem arising from the separation of
ownership and control is a serious one and does concentrated ownership
effectively overcome these problems? The
principle-agent model suggests that managers are less likely to engage in
strictly profit maximising behaviour in the absence of strict monitoring by
shareholders. Therefore, if
owner-controlled firms are more profitable than manager-controlled firms, it
would seem that insider systems have an advantage in that they provide better
monitoring which leads to better performance.
The vast majority of empirical studies, it turns out, do seem to favour
the beneficial effects of enhanced monitoring as a result of higher ownership
concentration.
Gugler (1999)
provides a comprehensive survey of empirical studies of the effects of
ownership concentration on corporate performance, beginning with the seminal
work of Berle and Means (1932) to more recent work by Leech and Leahy (1991),
Prowse (1992), Agrawal and Knoeber (1996), and Cho (1998). Based primarily on studies from the US and
UK, he finds that although the results are ambiguous, the majority of studies
find that “owner-controlled” firms significantly outperform “manager-controlled”
firms. Firms are usually classified as
owner controlled if there is a single block of equity exceeding 5 or 10
percent. The dependent variable used in
these studies were are all proxies for the performance of the firms as measured
by net income/net worth, rate of return on equity or Tobin’s Q, or the
riskiness of returns. Although a number
of studies find no significant difference between the two, the number of
studies that find that manager-controlled firms outperform owner-controlled
firms is negligible.
On balance,
therefore, the empirical evidence is supportive of the hypothesis that large
shareholders are active monitors in companies, and that direct shareholder
monitoring helps boost the overall profitability of firms. This result is also borne out by studies of
managerial turnover. For example, Franks
and Mayer (1994) find a larger turnover of directors when large shareholders
are present, again indicating that large shareholders are active monitors. It seems, therefore, that the beneficial effects
of direct monitoring, and a better match between cash flow and control rights,
more than outweigh the costs of low diversification opportunities or rent
extraction by majority owners.
Although the
evidence points to a greater role and fewer restrictions for large
shareholders, the policy implications of these results should be viewed with
caution. One of the problems with the
numerous studies that exist on the effects of ownership concentration on
corporate performance is that they are all based on US or UK samples of firm
data. There are some exceptions however,
notably, Round (1976, Australian), Thonet and Poensgen (1979, German),
Jacquemin and Ghellinck (1980, French), and Prowse (1992, Japanese). For example, Thonet and Poensgen (1979) found
that for a sample of listed German manufacturing firms, manager-controlled
firms significantly outperform owner-controlled firms in terms of
profitability, but that owner-controlled firms had higher growth rates. Jacquemin and Ghellinchk (1980), using French
firm data, found no differences between familial and non-familial controlled
firms. Prowse (1992) also does not find any relationship between ownership
concentration and profitability in Japanese companies.
Although these
few studies are not conclusive evidence, they do highlight that the policy
conclusions of the results based on US and UK data are not necessarily
transferable to other countries. In the
US and UK, levels of ownership concentration are low relative to other
countries. Therefore, although it may be
true that more direct shareholder monitoring, fewer restrictions for large
shareholders, and more ownership concentration improves performance in the US
and UK, this may not be the case in countries where ownership concentration is
already relatively high. Once
concentration levels reach very high levels then it is not clear that more
monitoring will continue to improve things and may actually work in the
opposite direction. In fact, empirical
studies for both the US and UK suggest that at low levels of concentration,
performance[22]
increases as concentration increases, but then declines as concentration levels
keep increasing, see Morck, Shleifer and Vishny (1988), McConnell and Servaes
(1990), Wruck (1989), and Franks, Mayer and Renneboog (1995).
We must also keep
in mind that corporate governance structures are not static but dynamic in
nature. Recent changes in corporate
governance in the US and UK include the increased importance of institutional
investors, which also leads to reduced scope for management discretion, and can
act as a substitute for large shareholder monitoring. Furthermore, transferring the “separation of
ownership and control” view of monitoring as suggested by the large body of
primarily US and UK economic studies to Continental Europe, Korea, and Japan
can be misleading because the economic decision agents are very different from
the US/UK scene. Holding companies, the
state, banks, other non-financial corporations, and familial control are
dominant features in the rest of Europe, Korea, and Japan. Different owners will have different
objectives, and it is highly likely that the identity of owners will matter for
firm performance. For example, managers
of corporations under governmental or quasi-governmental control are likely to
have different incentives and will, therefore, behave differently to managers
of corporations in the private sector.
For this reason, ownership concentration and the identity of owners
should be viewed as variables that exert a simultaneous, but different,
influence on firm performance.
In addition, Roe
(1994) states that the low ownership concentration in the US compared to other
countries may be the result of policies initiated by controlling managers that
discourage large holdings e.g. anti-takeover devices. This implies, that for the US at least, that
managers are strong relative to shareholders and that management entrenchment
is a serious problem. Therefore, policy
makers in outsider systems like the US and UK should pay particular attention
to the negative effects of mechanisms that are often employed by management
that inhibit the market for corporate control.
Direct monitoring is just one of many devices that can be used to reduce
conflicts between managers and shareholders. Therefore, where direct
shareholder monitoring is weak, such as in outsider systems, policy makers need
to pay particular attention to the incentive effects created by other control
mechanisms such as take-overs or managerial remuneration schemes.
Furthermore,
whether or not owner-controlled firms outperform manager-controlled firms, may
depend not only on the initial levels of ownership concentration, but also on
the industry in question. A study by
Zeckhauser and Pound (1990) finds that whether or not owner-controlled firms
outperform manager-controlled firms does indeed depend on the type of
industry. They find that the superior
performance of owner-controlled firms holds in industries with relatively low
asset specificity (e.g. machinery and
paper products), but there was no difference in industries with high asset
specificity (e.g. computers).[23] This suggests that the nature of the firm’s
investment and production decisions influence the asymmetry of information
between principal and agent. For
example, in industries where outside monitoring is particularly difficult, such
as is the case in high asset specificity industries, large shareholders are
less effective in overcoming agency problems.
In this case, additional control mechanisms may be required (e.g. the number of outside directors on the
board, the managerial labour market, markets for corporate control, managerial
pay schemes, etc.).
The finding that
owner-controlled firms are more profitable than manager-controlled firms is
also consistent with the life-cycle model of the firm. Corporate governance failures and bad
investment decisions are less likely in the early stages of a firm’s life, a
time when investment opportunities are in abundance and equity stakes are
concentrated. However, as firms grow and
mature, not only does ownership become more diluted, but investment
opportunities also fall short of the cash flow available. Therefore, as firms
grow and mature, this provides greater incentives for the increasingly
unmonitored management to expropriate rents.
The dilution and dispersion of equity stakes in this case, implies that
as firms mature effective corporate governance mechanisms become increasingly
important in assuring firm performance.
Finally, several
studies also stressed the importance of the effects of product market
competition on managerial behaviour. For
example, significant differences in the performance of owner-controlled versus
manager-controlled firms are more likely in markets where the scope for
managerial entrenchment is much higher i.e.
in monopolistic or oligopolistic market structures. This is because in competitive markets there
are fewer rents for management to expropriate, hence, ownership structure is
less likely to affect firm performance.
Weaknesses in corporate governance are, therefore, more likely when firms
are both management-controlled and when firms exert a high level of market
power. One of the policy implications
arising from these findings is that developments in corporate governance
legislation should be developed in conjunction with competition and anti-trust
policy.
IV.2 Dominant shareholders and the expropriation of minority shareholders
The presence of
large shareholders improves the supervision of management and, thereby,
enhances firm performance. However,
there is the very serious problem that controlling blockholders or majority
shareholders can use the firm for their own private benefit, expropriating
rents at the expense of minority shareholders and other stakeholders. This ex-post expropriation by controlling
shareholders is likely to lead to sub-optimal levels of investment by minority
investors and other stakeholders. After
all, unless the targets of expropriation are adequately protected, they have a
reduced incentive to provide firmspecific investments in the first place. In addition, when minority investors are less
willing to provide equity finance, this can lead to illiquid stock markets and
reduced diversification possibilities for investors. Therefore, given the
consequential impacts for innovative activity, entrepreneurship and economic
growth, it is important to know whether or not expropriation is a problem.
Direct evidence
on measuring the extent of expropriation of rents, by either large shareholders
or controlling blockholders (which may include management), is difficult to
obtain. Therefore, empirical studies
have attempted to measure this in an indirect way. If control is associated with the ability to
expropriate private benefits, then the market should value “control”. In this case, we would expect to see
controlling shares trading at a premium.
For example, if shares with superior voting rights trade at a premium,
which is not accounted for by other factors[24],
then this is taken as evidence for significant private benefits of control that
may come at the expense of minority shareholders.
In surveys of
corporate governance, Shleifer and Vishny (1997) and Gugler (1999) find that
the empirical evidence suggests that control is valued, which would not be the
case if controlling blockholders or large shareholders received the same
benefits as other investors. For
example, Barclay and Holderness (1989, 1992) find that in the US, large blocks
of equity trade at a substantial premium to the post-trade price of minority
shares, and that on average these blocks trade at a 20% premium. This supports the hypothesis that purchasers
of the block of shares that may have a controlling influence receive private
benefits. Other studies, taking a
different approach, also support this hypothesis by comparing the price of
shares that have identical dividend rights but differential voting rights. For the US, DeAngelo and DeAngelo (1985),
Jarrell and Poulsen (1988), and Zingales (1995) find that shares with superior
voting rights trade at a premium, but that this premium is small. However, Zingales (1995) finds that the
premium rises sharply in situations where control is contested, again implying
that controlling blockholders receive private benefits at the expense of
minority shareholders.
Evidence from
other countries, where concentrated ownership is the norm, suggests that
expropriation of private benefits by controlling blockholders at the expense of
other stakeholders is a major problem.
While Rydqvist (1987) and Bergstrom and Rydqvist (1990) find a
relatively low premium for Sweden, studies on Israel, Italy, and Switzerland
find substantial premiums. For example,
while Rydqvist (1987) finds a 6.5% average voting premium for Sweden, Levy
(1982) finds a 45.5% premium in Israel, Horner (1988) finds a 20% premium for
Switzerland, and Zingales (1994) finds a 82% voting premium on the Milan Stock
Exchange. The large voting premium in
Italy suggests high private benefits of control, and Zingales (1994) and Barca
(1995) suggest that managers in Italy divert profits to themselves at the expense
of non-voting shareholders. Zingales
also measures the average proportion of private benefits to be around 30% of
firm value.
The empirical
evidence on Israel and Italy, therefore, suggests that agency costs can be very
large in some countries. Zingales (1994)
conjectures that these private benefits of control are so large in Italy
because the legal system is ineffective in preventing exploitation by
controlling blockholders. This suggests
that the development (or strengthening) of policies aimed at protection of
minority shareholders may be particularly needed in countries with relatively
weak corporate governance or legal systems that enable such expropriation to
take place. For example, systems
characterised by pyramidal groups can further exacerbate the problem, since
small shareholders can also be expropriated through inter-group transfers.[25] However, even if one instituted corporate
governance policies with strong protection of minority shareholders, it is
likely the policies will be ineffective if legal systems remain weak. Therefore, what is required is a systemic
approach, which demands that problems in the legal and regulatory structure be
address simultaneously with changes in corporate governance policies.
Indirect evidence
has also been obtained from empirical studies relating firm performance to
insider ownership, i.e. to manager or
director holdings. Morck et. al. (1988), for a sample of US
firms, find a positive relationship between board ownership and firm
performance in the 0-5% ownership range, a negative relationship between 5-25%,
and a positive influence of management ownership beyond the 25% level. Morck et.
al. conclude that their findings are consistent with the hypothesis that at
first “convergence of interests” effects dominate and managers have greater
incentives to maximise firm value as their ownership stakes rise, yet their
stakes are too small to become entrenched.
As their ownership stakes rise, then “management entrenchment” outweighs
“convergence of interests”, but beyond 25% “convergence of interests” effects
dominate again. McConnell and Servaes
(1990) and Belkaoui and Pavlik (1992) obtain similar results.
On the other
hand, using US data, Holderness and Sheehan (1988a,b) do not find any
differences, and Asquith and Wizman (1990) find only small - if any - transfers
between stakeholders. Their results
would imply a rejection of the hypothesis that expropriation of minority
shareholders is the primary reason for majority ownership. However, both the strong evidence and level
of expropriation found in other countries, suggest that this conclusion is only
valid for the US. It could well be the
case that strong protection of minority investors in the US may prevent
controlling shareholders from expropriation by other shareholders. The evidence suggests that in many other
countries expropriation remains a major problem.
Since
expropriation by controlling shareholders can deter minority investors, the
result is often a small and illiquid public equity market. This would explain why, in countries where
expropriation is a major problem, capital markets remain underdeveloped
relative to the US and UK. La Porta et. al. (1997) ranked investor
protection according to a number of dimensions of shareholder and creditor
protection.[26]The
authors find that investors are best protected in English common law countries,
are somewhat protected by German and Scandinavian codes, and are most
vulnerable in countries of French origin. They find that good shareholder
protection is one determinant of liquid equity markets. Table 4 in section III also shows that stock
markets play a much larger role in countries like the UK and US, where investor
protection is high, than in Continental Europe countries, such as Austria,
Italy, Spain and Germany, where minority shareholder protection is weaker. This is because when expropriation is limited
by law minority investors anticipate higher returns and are ready to pay more
for shares. This can induce controlling
shareholders to reduce their stakes or give up control, which in turn, leads to
more liquid markets and dispersed ownership.
Small and illiquid
equity markets need not be a concern if other sources of finance (internal and
external) still lead to an optimal level and mix of investment. However, it is not clear whether debt finance
is an adequate substitute for equity finance for all types of investment. This is particularly the case in industries
where there is a great deal of asset specificity, and where uncertainty and
risks are high e.g. high technology
industries. There is evidence to suggest
that R&D investment might be adversely affected when the main source of
outside finance is debt. In addition,
the higher risk and greater asymmetry of information associated with R&D
projects in comparison to standard investments in physical capital stock especially
inhibits new high-tech firms from obtaining bank loans, see Gugler (1999). Figure 1 below depicts the relationship
between stock market capitalisation and R&D spending for 14 OECD countries
in 1994. A regression of the effect of
the ratio of stock market capitalisation to GDP on the R&D/GDP ratio shows
that a 10% point “deepening” of a country’s stock market increases the
R&D/GDP ratio by about 0.12 percentage points. This result is also confirmed in studies by
Long and Malitz (1985) and Bradley et.
al. (1984), who find a negative correlation between leverage and R&D
activity. It would seem therefore that
countries with liquid equity markets tend to invest more in R&D activity
and high-tech firm start-ups. This finding has implications for a country’s
future productivity and growth.
Overall, the
empirical evidence therefore supports the view that there are potential
conflicts of interest between dominant shareholders and other stakeholders in
the firm, and that there are detrimental effects associated with
expropriation. The source of this
conflict is not just the structure of ownership but is also due, in part, to
the legislative framework which protect investor rights. While Barclay and Holderness (1992) argue
against legal provisions that may inhibit or postpone the exercise of control
by acquirers of large blocks, such prescriptions seem inappropriate in a
continental European context where the protection of minority shareholders is
much weaker. Recent legislative changes
in some European countries are indeed aimed at correcting the expropriation of
rents by controlling shareholders and at moving in the direction of enhanced
minority shareholder protection. These
legislative moves include preventing acquirers of large blocks from voting
their shares until approved by other shareholders, or preventing these
blockholders from purchasing the remaining shares for a specified price. For example, in Italy, Belgium, Denmark, and
France, laws were passed that every acquisition of more than 30% of the equity
of the firm be followed by a tender offer to all voting shares at the same
price.
The challenging task
facing policy makers is to design corporate governance frameworks that secure
the benefits of large shareholders as effective monitors of management whilst
preventing them from extracting excessive private benefits of control. A framework that effectively protects
minority shareholders from expropriation will encourage the development of
equity markets since small investors are then willing to invest in companies’
stocks. For example, on the one hand,
non-voting stock is both a low cost instrument for remaining in control and
raising outside equity capital. On the
other hand, it is also a separation device that implies diluted incentives and
facilitates shareholder expropriation.
Therefore, the best policy response seems to be to allow (but restrict)
the issuance of non-voting stock, while at the same time provide minority
shareholders with the means and power to claim due compensation if expropriation
arises. High standards of disclosure and
transparency also help ensure the type of environment in which small
shareholders feel comfortable investing in equity markets. Disclosure requirements for pyramidal groups,
for the structure of ownership and voting rights, and for legal separation
devices, should be mandatory and enforcement should be strict, see the policy
recommendations of the OECD Principles of Corporate Governance (1999a).
Figure 1. Stock market
capitalisation and the R&D/GDP ratio in 1994
Stock market capitalization and the R&D/GDP
ratio
Stock market capitalization (% of GDP)
Source: Gugler (1999)
IV.3 The market for corporate control and firm performance
It is often
asserted that takeovers are a mechanism for removing the management of poorly
performing firms. Takeovers act as a
powerful disciplining tool since they enable anyone who identifies an
underperforming company to buy a controlling interest and to reap any gains
associated with transferring control from an inefficient management to an
efficient one. In market based systems
of corporate governance, such as the US and the UK, takeovers play a key role
in the disciplining management. However, when we look at takeover activity
outside the US and UK we find that there are very few hostile takeovers. In continental Europe, for example, capital
markets are much smaller and controlling shareholders act as monitors, and
there tends to be little reliance on the market for corporate control as a
disciplining device. Therefore, some of
the questions that the empirical literature attempts to address are to what
extent takeovers are a good substitute for direct shareholder monitoring to
control management and what are the efficiency consequences of takeovers?
However, the
efficiency of takeovers as a disciplining mechanism is a controversial and
somewhat unresolved issue. There is the
problem that too few hostile takeovers appear to be value improving, and some
even appear to result in outright reductions in value. There are several reasons why not all
takeovers will serve to enhance firm value.
Firstly, the main objective of the bidder need not necessarily be profit
maximisation. For example, managerialist
theories of the firm emphasise the size and growth objectives of managers, and
one of the fastest ways to increase firm growth is to acquire another firm.[27] Secondly, although there may be improvements
in productive efficiency, takeovers may adversely affect dynamic efficiency by
reducing firm-specific investment by various stakeholders. For example, if stakeholders anticipate that
takeovers increase the probability that they will be expropriated ex-post they
may provide sub-optimal levels of firm-specific investment ex-ante.[28]
Thirdly, an active takeover market may only aggravate excessively short termist
behaviour that can impinge on innovative activity and dynamic efficiency.[29]
There are two
approaches to analysing the effects of takeovers. One approach is to examine the share prices
of the target and acquiring firms around the announcement date of the
takeover. In reviewing the empirical
evidence on takeovers that adopts this approach, the following facts have emerged. The vast majority of empirical studies seem
to find that target shareholders, on average, earn positive returns from tender
offers. For example, Jarrell and Poulsen
(1987a) using a large sample of successful tender offers in the US, estimate
the premia to average 19% during the 1960’s, 35% in the 1970’s, and 39% in the
1980’s. Higson and Elliot (1998) find similar results for the UK during the
1975-1990 period, where returns to target shareholders averaged 37% and were
positive in 88% of the cases. Many other
studies confirm these results.[30] On the other hand, for bidder shareholders
the returns, on average, are close to zero.
For example, for results on bidder returns in the US, see Bradley et. al. (1984), and for the UK, see
Franks and Harris (1989). Overall, the
empirical evidence indicates that it is target shareholders that, on average,
are the winners of takeover contests.
Another approach
to analysing the effects of takeovers is to look at the post-takeover
performance of the merged group. The
desirability of takeovers from a social point of view is a matter of whether
the observed takeover gains for target shareholders represent real gains or
just reflect transfers of wealth from one economic agent to another. Mergers and takeovers benefit society and are
socially desirable as long as efficiency gains are observed. These gains can be due to the disciplining of
inefficient management, as well as gains from economies of scale and scope, to
the savings of transaction costs or other synergies. If takeovers are a means of resolving problems
associated with inefficient management, or with other efficiency gains, than
the ex-post performance of the merger group should be better than the weighted
average of the ex-ante performance of the acquiring and target firm prior to
the takeover.
The vast majority
of studies find no significant improvement in firm performance following a merger.
In fact, most find a negative impact on performance, particularly in the
case of unrelated or conglomerate mergers.
On the other hand, hostile
takeovers, do not exhibit the same deterioration in performance as mergers.[31] While some studies show small, but
significant, post-hostile-takeover returns, others find no significant
efficiency gains.[32] While the evidence on hostile takeovers is
more positive, some authors express doubt that the takeover process is an
effective means for disciplining management, see Ravenscraft and Scherer (1987)
and Franks and Mayer (1996). In this
case, an active market for corporate control in the US and UK does not
necessarily reflect the extent to which managerial inefficiencies are being
corrected. These results, therefore,
raise serious concerns regarding the strong reliance on hostile takeovers as
the primary means of monitoring management in outsider systems.
These results
also raise concerns regarding the motives behind many mergers. Since the efficiency gains of takeovers are,
at best, quite low and target shareholders are receiving average premia of
around 30% to 40%, takeovers seem to be primarily motivated by other objectives
rather than with the disciplining of management. Franks and Mayer (1996) found that there was
little evidence that takeovers in the US and UK were motivated by poor
performance prior to the takover bid and, hence, are primarily motivated by
other objectives, such as changes in corporate strategy, or rent seeking
behaviour. Tax motives, in particular,
have long been suspected as a contributor to merger and acquisition activity,
and the available evidence seems to support this, for example, see Auerbach and
Reishus (1988), Lehn and Poulsen (1987), and Bhagat et. al. (1990).
Since efficiency
gains are small, the vast majority of studies find that target shareholder’s
gains come primarily at the expense of other stakeholders, labour in
particular. While most of these studies
find that employees losses mainly come in the form of layoffs, reduced wages,
or lower employment and wage growth, Pontiff et. al. (1990) found that over 10% of takeovers involve pension
fund reversions, accounting for 10% to 13% of takeover premia.[33] The fact that labour looses from takeovers
can have long-term implications for investment, by reducing stakeholders’
incentives to provide firm-specific investment.
In addition, takeovers can also have (positive or negative) externalities
not captured by the firm’s stakeholders (including shareholders). For example, Shliefer and Summers (1988)
point out that the acquisition of Youngstown Sheet and Tube in 1970 resulted in
more that a doubling of bankruptcies in Youngstown and a plummeting of house
prices. Therefore, the sudden
redeployment of corporate assets, which can occur in some takeovers, can have
major impacts on whole cities and regions.
While the
evidence does not seem to support the hypothesis that takeovers act to rectify managerial
inefficiencies, this does not mean that policy makers need not worry about
mechanisms that inhibit the market for corporate control. Even if there is no evidence that takeovers
actually improve firm performance, this does not necessarily imply that the
market for corporate control does not work as a disciplining device. This is because the mere threat of a takeover may serve this function. Therefore, the fact that we do not observe
takeovers that are motivated with the disciplining of management but, instead,
are motivated by other objectives, does not mean that the market for corporate
control is not an effective disciplining device, since it is the threat that
serves as the mechanism. Therefore,
serious concern has been expressed recently regarding the use of defensive or
anti-takeover mechanisms, particularly those that do not require shareholder
approval, and which inhibit the market for corporate control. These measures include poison pills, greenmail[34],
or state anti-takover amendments[35].
The late 1980’s witnessed a sharp
increase in the number of states in the US adopting anti-takeover legislation
and firms adopting poisons pills. For
example the percentage of listed firms that were protected by such legislation
increased from 38% in 1987 to 77% in 1988.[36]
In fact, the
empirical evidence supports the view that policy makers should worry about the
use of measures that inhibit the market for corporate control. Nearly all of the studies that look at the
welfare effects of anti-takeover measures find that these measures reduce
shareholder value. For example, Jarrell
and Poulsen (1987b) report significant negative stock-price effects associated
with supermajority amendments; OCE (1984) find negative stock price effects
associated with greenmail; and Malatesta and Walkling (1988) and Ryngaert
(1988) find that poison pills harm target shareholders by reducing the
probability of takeovers. More recently,
Bertrand and Mullainathan (1999) examined the effects of state anti-takeover
legislation, in particular, business combination (BC) legislation[37]
and find that these laws raised annual wages by 1% to 2%. Their results imply that takeovers do act to
discipline management since they reduce the scope for managerial discretion
i.e. uncontrolled managers that are protected by antitakeover legislation pay
higher wages.[38] The authors conclude that BC, by impose a
moratorium on specified transactions (e.g. sale of assets, mergers, and
business relationships) between the target firm and the acquiring firm, unless
the board votes otherwise, are
effectively giving the board the power to block hostile takeovers and help to
entrench management. Jensen (1988) also
points out that these defensive measures, by inhibiting the market for
corporate control, raise serious concerns since they are effectively transferring
critical control decisions from owners to managers, in particular, the right to
make decisions regarding the firing of management.
In summary,
although the evidence taken from actual takeovers does not seem to support the
hypothesis that takeovers are an effective mechanism for disciplining poor
management, evidence based on the use of anti-takeover amendments, suggests
otherwise. This implies that it is the
threat of takeover, rather than actual takeovers, that seems to act as an
effective device. Mechanisms that
inhibit the market for corporate control should therefore be viewed with
apprehension. Furthermore, even if
takeovers served only to correct instances of managerial inefficiency, legal,
advisory and financing costs total, on average, 4% of the purchase price. This is a particularly expensive way of
aligning the interests of management with those of shareholders. Franks and Mayer (1996) conclude that there
is a tradeoff between different methods of correcting managerial failure.
While takeovers on the one hand may lead to
lower levels of managerial inefficiencies, they may also come at the expense of
long-term firm-specific investment.
Takeovers, therefore, should be viewed in conjunction with other control
devices. For example, if one thinks that
hostile takeovers are harmful to the economy, but if substitutive relationships
exist, one could strengthen these alternative mechanisms while not constraining
hostile takeovers by regulation. For
example, Fama and Jensen (1983) and Kini et.
al. (1995) find that takeovers can serve as a substitute for outsider
directors i.e. they are a good
control mechanism when there are few outside directors on the board. Brickley and James (1987) found that in
states where takeovers are more restricted, the number of outside directors and
ownership concentration are effective substitutive mechanisms for
monitoring. Schranz (1993) also finds
substitutability between ownership concentration and takeovers as disciplining
devices. In conclusion, although there
are concerns regarding the effectiveness of hostile takeovers as a disciplining
device, the evidence seems to suggest that the market for corporate control
should be allowed to function without restriction. However, to rely on hostile takeovers as the
only, or even the main, disciplinary device is not optimal either.
IV.4 Managerial compensation and firm performance
When other direct
control mechanisms do not function very well, there may be a need for special incentives that induce managers to
act in the interests of shareholders i.e.
to maximise profits. This is often undertaken through the design of executive
remuneration packages. In practice this
usually involves tying managerial compensation to the performance of the firm,
in the form of salaries, bonuses, and stock options. In this way, managerial wealth is subjected
to at least some of the same risks to which shareholders and the firm are
exposed. Therefore, linking managerial
compensation to firm performance has been adopted in many countries as a way of
aligning the interests of managers with those of shareholders. However, managerial compensation has become a
hotly debated issue, particularly in the US and UK, where the last 10 years
have seen an explosion in the level of managerial pay.
The emphasis on
executive remuneration packages varies from one country to another and the
optimality of contingent performance based compensation depends on whether or
not other direct monitoring alternatives are available. In Japan and Germany, for example, executive
pay tends to be considerably lower than in the US and UK. This may reflect the closer relationship between
controlling shareholders and managers that exists in insider systems. For example, in insider systems of corporate
governance there is less scope for managerial discretion and there are fewer
informational asymmetries between managers and owners. Kole (1997) provides empirical evidence
supporting this hypothesis. He finds
that for 371 Fortune 500 firms in 1980, that if there is a family
representative either in management or on the board of directors, the probability
of adopting an equity-based compensation plan is significantly reduced. Conyon and Leech (1993) also find that the
level of director pay is lower in companies that have a higher share ownership
concentration or are defined as owner-controlled. In addition, the prevalence of longer term contracts
in Japan, coupled with the fact that most managers are promoted internally,
means that reputation may provide a sufficient deterrent to managers without
the need for explicit incentive contracts.
Therefore, it is not surprising that managerial compensation tends to be
lower in insider systems, such as Germany and Japan, than that found in the US
and UK.
While the
empirical evidence confirms the substitutive effects between direct monitoring
by owners and compensation incentives, board monitoring or monitoring by
institutional investors may also substitute for direct shareholder
monitoring. In theory at least, the use
of these other mechanisms should also reduce the level of pay-incentives needed
to align managers’ incentives with those of shareholders. In practice, however, board members become
like management and agency costs are expected.
Mehran (1995) finds empirical evidence to support this view. He finds that the presence of outside
directors, rather than decreasing the level of executive remuneration, actually
increases the percentage of equity-based compensation. Separating the roles of chairman and CEO is
often proposed as a way of preventing boards from becoming entrenched like
management and, in principle, should increase accountability. However, Conyon and Leech (1993) found no
evidence that separating the roles of chairman and CEO had any effect on
executing compensation levels. And as
regards whether or not monitoring by institutional investors has a substitutive
effect with compensation incentives, Cosh and Hughes (1997) do not find any
evidence that institutional holdings in the UK alter the level of executive
remuneration or the pay-performance relationship. Therefore, while direct shareholder
monitoring is a good substitute for compensation incentives, the evidence
suggest that the board and monitoring by institutional investors, on the other
hand, are relatively weak monitoring devices and not a good substitute for
direct monitoring.
If the use of
incentive devices is effective, then this should manifest itself in a positive
relationship between managerial compensation and firm performance. Excluding stock options, current evidence
indicates that sensitivities of pay to performance are quite small. Murphy (1985), Coughlin and Schmidt (1985)
and Barro and Barro (1990) all find pay-performance elasticities in the range
0.10 to 0.17, suggesting that a 10% rise in firm profitability leads to a 1% to
1.7% rise in CEO compensation consisting of salary plus bonus. However, Hall and Liebman (1997) suggest that
previous sensitivity measures ignored changes in the value of stock and stock
options, which account for virtually all of the sensitivity. From a sample
based on 478 large US companies from 1980 to 1994, the authors obtain similar
results as the rest of the empirical literature regarding the sensitivity of
performance to salary-plus-bonus (e.g. an elasticity of 0.2). They show that the driving force behind the
pay-performance relationship is the use of both stock and stock options. When the authors include stock and stock
options, they find a mean elasticity of 4.5, suggesting a 10% rise in
performance leads to a 45% increase in CEO remuneration.
However, Murphy
(1998) finds that most of this increase is attributable to a general increase
in the stock market and that there is little evidence that higher
pay-performance sensitivities lead to higher stock performance.
Some studies have
looked at the relationship between managerial compensation and firm’s sales.
Baker et. al. (1988) find the
elasticity of executive annual-salary-plus-bonus with respect to sales is in
the 0.20 to 0.25 range and is relatively uniform across firms, industries, and
time periods. While this finding is
consistent with value maximisation if larger firms employ better qualified and
better paid CEOs, it is also an indication that managers may not be behaving in
an optimal way. In fact, a number of
studies find that company size, and changes in size, are much more significant
determinants of executive pay than measures of shareholder value, see Main et. al. (1994), Conyon and Leech (1993),
and Gregg et. al. (1993). Since one of the fastest ways to increase
firm size is to acquire another firm, this empirical evidence suggests that
managers have an incentive to engage in mergers and acquisitions, which may not
be in the best interest of the corporation, but would have the effect of
increasing their remuneration.
According to
agency theory, remuneration contracts are efficient if the level of
compensation is linked to aspects of performance over which managers have some
control. Otherwise, executives would not
have any incentive to engage in significant effort to increase firm performance
since they know they will be compensated regardless of the performance of the
firm. For example, it does not make
sense for owners to compensate managers for events that are beyond their
control e.g. better firm performance
due to a general rise in the stock market.
Nor do owners want to penalise (fire) managers due to negative outcomes
that are not the fault of the manager e.g.
poor performance due to a recession.
However, it is harder for an executive manager to claim that the company
has performed poorly due to general market conditions if other benchmark
companies are performing well. This says that contracts, in order to be
efficient, should relate compensation to rises in relative performance e.g. the performance of industry peers
or direct competitors.
While the use of
relative comparisons makes managerial incentives more effective and
remuneration contracts more efficient, the empirical evidence concerning
relative performance effects is rather negative. For example, Murphy (1985), Barro and Barro
(1990), and Hall and Liebman (1997) find that, in general, managerial compensation
does not depend upon the relative performance of the firm. One of the reasons why this may be the case
is that, under current accounting rules, stock options with a performance
target have to be counted as a cost against profits, while options with a fixed
exercise price do not reduce current earnings.
One policy recommendation, therefore, is to harmonise accounting rules
concerning stock options with a variable and a fixed exercise price. Boards in this case would no longer be
discouraged from linking stock options to performance.
Given the
importance in outsider systems of stock and stock options as part of overall
managerial compensation particular attention needs to be paid to the design of
executive remuneration packages. In the
UK, the Cadbury Committee recommended that there should be a remuneration
committee that determines the level of executive compensation, and that this
committee should consist mainly of nonexecutive directors. While this suggestion is valuable, Ezzamel
and Watson (1997) find there are asymmetric adjustments in executive pay levels
i.e. executives that were relatively
underpaid in the previous period receive pay increases, whereas executives who
were overpaid were not subjected to downward adjustments. This is consistent with the complaint of many
shareholder groups that remuneration committees, rather than strengthening the
pay-performance relationship, have the effect of bidding up executive pay.
These empirical
findings raise serious concerns regarding not only the efficiency of executive
remuneration contracts, but also the motives behind them. For example, when agency problems are severe
and monitoring of management is very weak, executive remuneration, unless
efficiently designed, can become another vehicle for managerial expropriation
of rents. Because boards of directors
set compensation contracts, there is a serious concern that boards align
themselves more with management than with weak dispersed shareholders. Empirical evidence supporting this hypothesis
is obtained by Yermack (1997), who finds that the timing of stock option awards
coincides with favourable movements in company stock prices.[39] This suggests that managers who become aware
of impending improvements in corporate performance may be influencing the board
of directors to award more equity-based-performance pay. Furthermore, the practice of re-pricing stock
options when share prices fall, makes a complete mockery out of the notion that
options are designed to align the interest of managers with those of
shareholders.[40]
Executive
compensation plans may also serve to exacerbate short-termist behaviour. For example, by contributing to managers’
incentives to increase short-term shareholder value, the spread of share
options may be contributing to a temporary over-evaluation of equities and may
be distorting the economy. There are
serious concerns regarding the current practice of management to issue debt and
use the proceeds to buy back equity, thereby increasing the firm’s share
price. While in theory how a firm is
financed should make no difference to its value, very high levels of corporate
debt make a firm more vulnerable to bankruptcy in the event of a downturn.
Overall, the
empirical evidence seems to indicate that these contracts, rather than aligning
the interests of managers and shareholders, are enabling managers to
expropriate some of the rents from shareholders. These abuses are particularly likely when
share ownership is fragmented and alternative control mechanisms are weak. A study undertaken by the accountancy firm
PwC suggests that many companies in the UK were failing to achieve a link
between pay and performance. For
example, they found that for a sample of 270 quoted companies, only 7 firms put
their remuneration report to a shareholder vote, and only 5% of companies
disclosed even in broad terms how performance measures relate to long-term
company objectives.[41]
All of this does
not suggest that the use of share and share options should be restricted,[42]
but rather that they should be more closely linked to performance. The fundamental question, however, is whether
or not shares and share options are achieving what they were intended to do i.e. aligning the interest of managers
with those of shareholders. The evidence
in this regard is quite disappointing, and given the inherent conflict of
interest involved, the question arises whether the board of directors should
set key elements of managerial contracts at all. The empirical evidence in this regard
suggests that it should be shareholders themselves that ultimately decide on
the level and shape of executive remuneration packages. This is also in line with recent
recommendations by the UK government.[43]
V. Conclusions
Corporate
governance affects the development and functioning of capital markets and
exerts a strong influence on resource allocation. In an era of increasing capital mobility and
globalisation, it has also become an important framework condition affecting
the industrial competitiveness and economies of Member countries. This paper set out to further develop our
understanding of corporate governance and its affect on corporate performance
and economic performance. In doing so,
it addresses some of the underlying factors that promote efficient corporate
governance, and examines some of the strengths, weaknesses and economic
implications associated with various corporate governance systems. It also provided a survey of empirical
evidence on the link between corporate governance, firm performance and
economic growth, identifying areas in which a consensus view appears to have
emerged in the literature and areas in which further research is still needed.
One of the most
striking differences between countries’ corporate governance systems is the
difference in the ownership and control of firms that exist across
countries. There are tradeoffs between
ownership concentration and voting power concentration. Systems of corporate governance can be distinguished
according to the degree of ownership and control and the identity of
controlling shareholders. In ‘outsider’ systems (notably the US and UK) of
corporate governance the basic conflict of interest is between strong managers
and widely dispersed shareholders. In
‘insider’ systems (notably Continental Europe and Japan), on the other hand,
the basic conflict is between controlling shareholders (or blockholders) and
weak minority shareholders.
There is no
single model of good corporate governance, and both insider and outsider
systemshave their strengths, weaknesses, and different economic
implications. Furthermore, the
effectiveness of different corporate governance systems is influenced by
differences in countries’ legal and regulatory frameworks, and historical and
cultural factors, in addition to the structure of product and factor markets.
Corporate governance mechanisms and their effectiveness also vary depending on
industry sectors and type of productive activity. For example, in industries characterised by
high asset specificity (such as many high-tech industries), monitoring is more
difficult and different mechanisms may be required in order to improve firm
performance. Identifying what
constitutes good corporate governance practice, and under what circumstances,
is a difficult task. The challenge,
therefore, is not only to identify the strengths and weaknesses in each
individual system or group of systems, but also to identify what are the
underlying conditions upon which these strengths and weaknesses depend.
The benefits of
concentrated ownership are that it brings more effective monitoring of
management and helps to overcome agency problems. However, the costs associated with
concentrated ownership are low liquidity and reduced possibilities for risk
diversification. Dispersed ownership
brings higher liquidity, which can be vital for the development of innovative
activity. On the other hand, it does not
encourage commitment and long-term relationships that might be required for
certain types of investments. For
example, when corporations are owned and controlled by each other, this can
reduce transaction costs and incentives to engage in opportunistic
behaviour. Stakeholders, therefore, have
a greater incentive to invest in relationship specific investment. On the other hand, this can also reduce the
level of product market competition.
Since equity markets
are important for R&D and innovative activity, entrepeneurship, and the
development of an active SME sector, corporate governance has an underlying
impact on economic growth and development.
Therefore, one of the main challenges facing policy makers is how to
develop a good corporate governance framework which can secure the benefits
associated with controlling shareholders acting as direct monitors, while at
the same time, ensuring that they do not expropriate excessive rents at the
expense of other stakeholders. The
empirical evidence to date seems to suggest that this is indeed a problem and
that protection of minority shareholders is critical to the development of equity
markets. Therefore, policy makers in insider systems need to pay particular
attention to developing corporate governance frameworks that will not hinder
the development of active equity markets.
Policy recommendations
should attempt to account for the interactions between corporate governance and
the institutional framework in the particular country. The search for good practice should be based
on an identification of what works in defined countries, to discern what broad
principles can be derived from these experiences, and to examine the conditions
for transferability of these practices to other countries. As this document has demonstrated, not only
will different improvements be called for in different systems but these
improvements will also depend upon the factors determining the effectiveness of
different systems. For example, some
systems and circumstances may have a need for policy adjustments in other areas
such as strengthening product market competition or removing distortions in
corporate governance mechanisms created by other regulations (e.g. rules
regarding the use of fixed or variable price stock options). Continued work in this area, therefore, will
continue to build on the work developed in this document and will aim to
specify what are the crucial improvements needed in different systems and in
different situations. This work will not undertake any specific surveys or
country specific reviews. It will be
based on a thematic approach and will continue to draw on empirical work
already done outside and within the Organisation. Wherever possible, it will also draw on work
undertaken by other Directorates particularly as regards outreach activities on
corporate governance.
[1] . See Shleifer and Vishny (1997), p. 741.
[2] . See, for example, Shleifer and Vishny (1997) and
Berglof (1997).
[3] . Mayer (1996), p. 11.
[4] . Blair (1995), p. 203.
[5] . Zingales (1997) also
defines a corporate governance system in the spirit of Williamson (1985) as a
“complex set of constraints that shape the ex-post bargaining over the quasi
rents generated in the course of the relationship”.
[6] . See Keasey, Thompson, and Wright (1997), p. 3.
[7] . Data on ownership
concentration should be viewed with caution since disclosure requirements in most
OECD countries relate not to ownership but to control.
[8] . Information and recent
work undertaken by the ECGN, including the data used in this paper, can also be
found on their web site at http://www.ecgn.org.
[9] . Largest shareholder does
not imply a single individual, but rather the equity holdings of a single
entity. This could be the holdings of an institutional investor or pension
fund, a bank, or another firm, or familial holdings, etc.
[10] . Figures for the German
DAX 30 and French CAC40 are atypical.
For example, there is a minimum turnover requirement for membership of
the DAX30, leading companies to widen their shareholder base in order to remain
in the index. Similarly, the CAC40 is an
unrepresentative group of the largest and most liquid companies on the
exchange.
[11] . See La Porta et.
al. (1998) and Shleifer and Vishny (1997).
[12] . There is a vast
literature, which this work on corporate governance does not address, on how
vertical and horizontal relationships can impinge upon market competition.
[13] . With dispersed
ownership, if shareholders are unhappy, they will just sell their shares (exit)
since they do not have the incentive, or the means available to them (voice),
to engage in direct shareholder monitoring.
[14] . Overall individual
share ownership has increased i.e. the percentage of the population that holds
equities has increased in both countries.
However, these shares tend to be held indirectly.
[15] . However, since in many
fields basic research feeds directly into industrial applications providing
measurable returns, not all basic research has been downgraded e.g.
biotechnology or computer science.
[16] . See R&D Magazine (1997).
[17] . Morck et. al.
(1988), p. 294.
[18] . See Mayer (1996), p. 19.
[19] . Mayer (1996), p. 24.
[20] . Microsoft corporation
is a good example of this i.e. it is the promotion and ability to retain human
capital within the firm, rather than external funds, that impacts upon the
firm’s performance.
[21] . See OECD (1995), Economic Survey of Italy.
[22] . Performance is measured by Tobin’s q.
[23] . High asset specificity
implies that investment is specific to the industry (or the firm) and has
relatively few alternative uses. The
opposite is true of low asset specificity investment.
[24] . In some cases,
non-voting stock have a preferred dividend.
Therefore, the observed premium must be what is left over after having
accounted for other differences in classes of shares, and which is then
attributable to the superior voting rights, i.e.
the premium associated with control.
[25] . For example, in a case
study of IRI, Zingales found that IRI sold its majority stake in Finsiel to
STET (which is controlled by IRI as well), at too high a price.
[26] . Some of the dimension
include one-share/one-vote, if proxy by mail is allowed, cumulative voting,
percentage of shares need to call an extraordinary shareholders meeting,
anti-director rights, mandatory dividends, etc.
[27] . See Mueller (1985).
[28] . See Shleifer and Summer (1988).
[29] . However, Jarrell et. al. (1988) state that no empirical
evidence has been found to support this theory.
For example, a study by the SEC’s Office of the Chief Economist (1985)
found that there was no difference in the probability of takeover depending on
whether or not firms had high R&D expenditures.
[30] . See Jensen and Ruback
(1983), Jarrell et. al. (1988),
DeAngelo et. al. (1984), or Franks
and Mayer (1996), just to name a few.
[31] . Firm performance is
usually taken as some measure of profitability, although a number of studies looked
at changes in productivity or growth rates following the merger/takeover.
[32] . Rather than list the
vast number of studies that find small, but positive results and those that
find no efficiency gains, see Gugler (1999) for a comprehensive survey of the
empirical results on hostile takeovers.
[33] . The fact that companies
do not have to share surpluses in their pension plans with their workers, even
if the workers contributed to the plans through money withheld from their
paychecks, raises a whole set of corporate governance issues that are beyond
the scope of this paper.
[34] . Greenmail occurs when
the management of the target firm ends the hostile takeover threat by
repurchasing the hostile suitor’s block of target stock at a premium.
[35] . For example,
supermajority amendments which increases the minimum approval required for
mergers and other important control transactions, or dual-class
recapitalisations i.e. the creation of classes of equity with differential
voting rights. Other amendments include:
control share acquisition, which require other shareholders to approve the
voting rights of a large shareholder; fair price, which require paying a ‘fair
price’ for all shares tendered; and business combination, which imposes a
moratorium of 3-5 years on specified transactions between the target and
raider, unless the board votes otherwise.
[36] . See Comment and Schwert (1995).
[37] . Ryngaert and Netter
(1988) and Schumann (1988) also present evidence on the negative effects of
state anti-takeover amendments.
[38] . There are several
reasons why managers may prefer to pay higher wages. Manager may care more about having
high-quality workers and lower turnover than owners do. They might care more than owners about
improving relations with employees since they are the ones who endure the
worker’s complaints and enjoy their company.
Also managers may dislike bargaining.
[39] . In particular, he finds
that in the 50 days immediately following CEO option awards, stock prices
experience an average cumulative abnormal return of more than 2%.
[40] . When share prices fell
in the late summer of 1998, many firms re-priced their options just in time so
that executives enjoyed massive gains when the market rebounded, see The
Economist, 7 August 1999.
[41] . See the Financial Times, 20 July, 1999.
[42] . For example, the use of
stock options can reduce the costs of starting a company since new firms can
hire employees with the promise of future benefits through the use of share
options. In this way, new high-tech
firms with no assets need not be penalised since they can now compete with more
established firms and attract high-quality employees by offering options.
[43] . For example, the UK
government has suggested that this could be done by either requiring companies
to put their remuneration report to an annual shareholder vote, or by allowing
shareholders to put forward resolutions on remuneration to annual general
meetings.
No comments :
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.