2.3 Identification of New Activities in-Motion Using ATUS Data
Analysis in this section uses
publicly available data from the 2011-2014 American Time Use Survey (ATUS).
ATUS involves computer-assisted telephone interviewing in which survey
respondents are interviewed on the next day of a pre-selected day about how
they spent their time from 4 AM on the pre-selected day to 4 AM of the
interview day (days are selected to ensure proportional distribution across the
days of the week and even distribution across the weeks of the year) (Basner,
et al., 2007). Each activity described by the respondent is coded using a
three-tiered scheme, going from a top-level category of activities, to
subcategories, and then to third-tier activities that describe very specific
actions. To provide a specific example, the top-level two-digit “traveling”
category includes a second-tier four-digit category of “traveling related to
caring for and helping household members” under which “travel related to caring
for and helping household children” is a third-tier activity with a six-digit
activity code.
ATUS data has a total of 465 six-digit activity codes, of
which 6 indicate missing data status and 459 indicate activity information.
Kenyon and Lyons’ (2007) had suggested that three attributes of activities may
be important to the extent to which activity in-motion is both possible and
desirable, including the degree of locational dependence, the degree of
continuity of engagement, and the degree of active attention. Based upon their
framework, the following two sets of activity attributes are important in
identifying possible activities in-motion during the era of self-driving and
better mobile technologies;
The degree of locational dependence
(e.g., park use) and the necessity of importable equipment (e.g., billiards)
The
degree of engagement continuity and desired comfort level (e.g., uninterrupted
sleeping)
The degree of active attention will eventually be no longer
important for enabling activity inmotion because, with fully self-driving cars,
travelers are able to pay full attention to and be fully engaged in other
activities. It is worth noting that,
because most existing research have been about activities during bus/rail trips
in public vehicles, the number of possible activities in-motion is likely to
increase significantly after self-driving cars.
Appendix A identifies possible activities that could be done in private
vehicles. These activities have rarely being studied in the travel time use
literature. They are:
A limited set of personal care activity
including dressing & grooming, health-related selfcare, personal/private
activities;
A
limited set of child care activities including reading to/with children, home
schooling, and arts and crafts with children;
Eating
and drinking;
Tobacco
and drug use; and
Participation
in religious practices.
Using the 2011-2014 ATUS data, Figure 2.3 presents the
average daily time spent on the above activities by U.S. population aged 15 or
older. On average, the U.S. population spent 118 minutes (roughly two hours) on
these identified activity types. Note that child care and personal care
activities included in Figure 2.3 are a limited set of these activities. Many
child care and personal activities are location dependent and/or require
importable equipment that cannot be conducted in travelling cars.
ATUS.
2.4 Impacts of the New Technologies
1. Unclear
implications on mode choice.
Evidence has shown that use of information and
telecommunication devices allows transit riders to stay connected, improves
transit experience, potentially increase transit mode choice and ridership.
Yet, there is also evidence that information and telecommunication technologies
(ICTs) are the least important mode choice factor among people older than
30. Whether increasing available ICTs on
public transit vehicles can shift people from driving to taking public transit
is dependent upon the general performance of transit services such as service
frequency, coverage, and reliability.
2. Bigger
and smaller cars.
Most existing prototype
self-driving cars appear to be small (see Figure 2.4 below). This is largely due
to the early state of the technologies and the recognition that most travel is
functional, for short distance trips, and involves one or two people. Further
electric vehicles are presently constrained by batteries, and so there is a
desire to limit vehicle weight to enable EVs.
Once the technologies are mature, there could be large market demand for
more space to increase activity options in the cars, particularly for longer
distance (intercity) trips. As shown in
Figure 2.3, most of the new activities require spaces for comfort levels, such
as child care, personal care, and eating and
Toyota Swagger Wagon Supreme as an example
of demand for more activity options in private cars.
3. Longer
trip distances and durations.
Mokhtarian and Salomon (2001)
suggested that excess travel is more likely to occur as people increase the
perceived positive utility of activities that can be conducted while traveling
and the utility of the activity of traveling itself. Because mobile technologies and self-driving
cars will make travelling effortless, increase activity options in the car, and
increase the productivity of travel time (as illustrated in Figure 2.5), it is
highly likely a significant amount of extra travel will occur.
Figure 2.5: Illustrative frequency
distribution of “utility” of travel time by mode (adapted based upon Lyons and
Urry, 2005)
4. Larger
spatial footprints with more trip chaining behaviors
Mobile technologies offer more
opportunities to replace hub-and-spoke trips toward a central point of gravity,
with circular trips chained together (Dal Fiore et al, 2014). The saved travel
time and the increased utility of travel are likely to encourage visits to more
distant but more attractive destinations (Dal Fiore et al, 2014).
Figure 2.6: A two-step
hypothesis on the implications of mobile technology for spatial behavior. Step
1: circular trips replace hub-and-spoke trips to and from a point of gravity;
Step 2: the number of trips increases
(and/or chosen destinations for existing trips change) due to increased
efficiency and information. (Figure downloaded from Dal Fiore et al, 2014)
5. Behavioral
impacts of technologies are likely to differ by gender, age, and SES.
Complex interaction effects are likely to occur when it
comes to how the technologies may affect trip distance, duration, activity
space, trip chaining, and car preferences across population groups. For
example, women have traditionally commuted shorter distances but travel more
for household support than men, which had led to limited economic opportunities
for women. Self-driving cars may enable women travel farther for jobs because
an increased number of personal care and child care activities can be done in
self-driving cars. Mobile technology and
self-driving cars may also enable women to travel less for errands because more
errands can be done online and self-driving cars encourage trip chaining
activity.
6. Societal
implications
Mobile technology and self-driving cars are likely to have
fundamental societal impacts such as transforming urban form and improving
transportation equity. For example, although technologies may encourage extra
travel for people with resources, they could also eliminate the needs for
travel and the needs for auto ownership among people with lower incomes (see Chapter 4).
Contingent on continued private vehicle ownership, people
will be more likely to make housing location choices based on their residential
preferences (such as school quality, neighborhood security, neighborhood
cohesion etc.) than based upon spatial accessibility. As people who own
autonomous vehicles are more willing to travel farther for more attractive
destinations, fewer but larger business centers are expected.
Chapter 3: Information and Communication Technologies
3.1 Introduction
It is well perceived that information and communication
technologies (ICT) have had pervasive impacts on modern society - they are
changing how and where we work, shop, and in other ways live our lives. ICT, particularly the Internet and mobile
service, make virtual activities a viable alternative to traditional physical
activities. The growing penetration of
ICT has important implications on transportation system. Unsurprisingly, transportation policy-makers
and planners expect tele-activities to replace some activities that require
travel between places and hence alleviate transportation and related problems
that many large metropolitan areas are confronting. However, research conducted during past
decades indicates that the impact of ICT on activity participation and travel
is more complex than it appears at first glance.
This report summarizes the effect of telecommuting and
teleshopping on individuals’ travel behavior based on the literature, and
discusses their potential impact on transportation system by 2040. It then
summarizes the effects of other tele-activities on travel. The final section offers an overall summary
and reviews reasons why ICT are unable, by themselves, to solve transportation
problems, but do bring about new challenges to our transportation systems.
3.2 Telecommuting
Telecommuting has grown
considerably during the past few decades.
Employees who primarily work at home increased by 61% from 2005 to 2009
and in 2010 about 16 million employees worked at home at least once a month, an
increase of 62% from 2005 (Lister and Harnish 2011). Telecommuting has particular appeal because
of its potential to reduce commute travel and traffic congestion during peak
hours, and energy consumption, and air pollution.
3.2.1 The impacts of telecommuting on
transportation
Conceptual and empirical studies
in the field of ICT and transportation suggest that telecommuting may interact
with travel behavior in four ways:
substitution, complementarity, modification, and neutrality (Salomon
1986, Mokhtarian 1990). Substitution
denotes that an individual works at home instead of making a physical trip to
her workplace. Complementarity means
that telecommuting generates new demands for other non-work trips. Modification denotes that telecommuting does
not affect the total amount of commute travel but changes the characteristics
of trips such as mode choice, timing, and chaining. Neutrality means that telecommuting has no
impacts on travel behavior. Among the
four ways, transportation planners are most interested in substitution.
The relationships between
telecommuting and travel behavior vary based on the measures of travel
behavior. For example, an individual
replaces a commute trip by working at home, but she makes a nonwork trip
because of time savings from not making the commute trip. In this case, the former represents a
substitution effect and the latter is a complementary effect. The net effect of telecommuting on total
travel depends on the characteristics of the commute and nonwork trips. If the
nonwork trip is longer than the commute trip, the net effect is
complementarity. If the nonwork trip is
shorter than the commute trip, the net effect is substitution. If the two trips have the same length but
take place at different times (such as peak vs. non-peak hours), the net effect
can be classified as modification.
Significant research has been conducted to understand the
impact of ICT on where work is done and how this affects travel. Not surprisingly, previous studies offer
mixed results. Pendyala et al. (1991)
found that telecommuters not only reduced commute trips, but also chose
non-work destinations close to their home.
By contrast, Gould and Golob (1997) found that telecommuters generated
new non-work trips, which offset the benefits of saved commute trips. Using the 1991 Caltrans Statewide Travel
Survey, Mokhtarian and Henderson (1998) found that home-based workers and
non-home-based workers made a similar number of trips: the savings from commute trips of home-based
workers are almost completely offset by the increase in their non-work
trips.
Several studies have found that
telecommuting is positively associated with commute distance (Mokhtarian, Handy
et al. 1995, Zhu 2012). Because researchers are unsure about which comes first,
telecommuting or residential location, the association may result from two
potential causes: One mechanism is that
individuals choose to telecommute because they want to reduce the cost
associated with their long commute distance; and the rival mechanism is that
individuals choose to live farther away from their workplaces because they are
able to telecommute (Ory and Mokhtarian 2006).
If the latter prevails, telecommuting may have an adverse effect on
VMT. For example, telecommuters may
choose to live in far-flung exurban or rural areas where they depend more on
private vehicles for their daily life than living in urban areas. Using the 2001 and 2009 National Household
Travel Survey (NHTS), Zhu (2012) explored the impacts of telecommuting on
travel behavior. He used the use of the
Internet as an instrument to predict the probability of telecommuting, and then
used the predicted probability of telecommuting to explain travel behavior. He found that telecommuting has positive
associations with the following behavioral variables: one-way commute distance,
one-way commute duration, total work-trip distance, total work-trip duration,
total work-trip frequency, total non-work-trip distance, total non-work-trip
duration, and total non-work-trip frequency.
Overall, he concluded that telecommuting did not reduce but increase
travel. By contrast, an aggregate time series analysis showed that
telecommuting reduced vehicle miles travelled (VMT) by about 0.8% or less
(Choo, Mokhtarian et al. 2005).
After reviewing more than 30 empirical studies, Andreev et
al. (2010) concluded that
telecommuting tends to reduce various measures of travel in
the short run, but its long-term impact is uncertain, partly because of induced
travel demand and residential location choice impacted by the ability of
telecommuting.
3.2.2 Trend analysis
In the American Community Survey (ACS), respondents were
asked to indicate “what was your primary means of transportation to work during
the survey week?” The choice set includes:
Car,
truck, or van - driving alone Car,
truck, or van - carpooled
Public
transportation Walked
Taxi,
motorcycle, or bike
Worked
at home
Work at home (WAH) is the third
commonly chosen primary means of transportation, after driving alone and
carpooling. In 2013, the share of
workers who worked at home was about 25% more than that of workers who took
public transportation[11]. Note that this underestimates the share of
less used modes, for instance, for people who work-at-home twice a week and
drive three times will be reported as driving by 100% of those
respondents.
Applying the logistic growth
curve to the ACS WAH data from 2005 to 2013, three different scenarios with
different saturation levels are presented in Figure 3.1. The low-saturation scenario assumes that WAH
workers will eventually account for 10% of the total workforce in the US. The rationale for this scenario is that
although WAH is generally growing, its growth is slow, on average at about 2.5%
annually during the past decade. The
share of WAH workers was at 4.4% in 2013 and it will take more than three
decades to reach the saturation level if the growth rate remains stable. The high-saturation scenario assumes that the
maximum level is at 40%. This is
consistent with Handy and Mokhtarian (1996). Their assumption was drawn from
Nilles’s assumption that “information workers” account for about 50% of the
work force, and 80% of information workers have the potential to telecommute
(Nilles 1988). Using California data, Handy and Mokhtarian also showed that the
assumption is consistent with “the characteristics of the California work force
and with studies of telecommuters” (p. 171). This saturation rate is also
consistent with the estimates of Global Workplace Analytics[12]: 50% of jobs are compatible with telework and
79% of workers want to telecommute (50%*79%=40%). The medium saturation rate is set at
20%. As shown in Figure 3.1, the share
of WAH workers will grow to 6.7% ~ 7.6% under the three scenarios by 2040. This represents an increase of 2.3 ~ 3.2
percentage points over the 2013 level.
The growth is not substantial, but it is also non-trivial because the
impact of travel reduction on congestion level is exponential.
It is worth noting that WAH workers in the Census or ACS
include self-employed workers such as farm, domestic, and service workers. Their home-based work does not substitute for
a commute so they are not telecommuters per se (Mokhtarian, Salomon et al.
2005). Therefore, we are likely to
misestimate the number of telecommuters.
In 2005, 3.62% of the work force worked at home. Excluding the self-employed workers, about
1.37% of workers considered their home primary workplace. That is, self-employed workers accounted for
about 2.24%. In 2012, employee
teleworkers totaled about 3.3 million[13],
accounting for 2.3% of the work force, whereas selfemployed workers accounted
for 2.03%.
Further, the ACS does not
consider occasional telecommuters, who do not choose home as their primary
workplace. That is, the ACS undercounts
the number of telecommuters. However,
because there is no consensus on how to define telecommuting, reliable
historical data on the number of telecommuters in the USA are not available
(Mokhtarian, Salomon et al. 2005).
WorldatWork Survey estimated that about 16 million workers telecommuted
at least once a month in 2010 (Lister and Harnish 2011). This accounted for about 11% of the work
force. This number is expected to grow.
However, in terms of telecommuting frequency, the followers tend to telecommute
less often than early adopters of telecommuting (Handy and Mokhtarian 1996).
However, telecommuting frequency should be smaller than this rate because
working at home includes work after regular hours and employees may work at
home partly while working at regular workplace.
The ACS does not capture those who work at other places such
as client offices, telecenters, coffee shops, and vehicles (Lister and Harnish
2011). In the 1990s, neighborhood
telecenters were promoted in California, under the sponsorship of the State of
California Department of
Transportation (Caltrans) with
funding from the Federal Highway Administration (Varma, Ho et al. 1998). However, the pilot program was not promising
and hence discontinued. There are also
53 million freelancers in the USA, who account for 34% of the work force[14]. Some of them work in coffee shops or
libraries although the exact number is unknown. Many freelance as a second or
third job.
An employees’ decision to telecommute and hence the
penetration of telecommuting is affected by employers’ attitudes toward
teleworking. Although telecommuting has
the potential to increase productivity and save office-related costs, managers
worry about the lack of team-building, commitment, and control (Baruch
2000). In 2013, Hewlett-Packard required
most of their employees to work at the office instead of from home in the name
of building engagement, collaboration and innovation[15]. Yahoo and Best Buy also implemented similar
polices to scale down or abandon their telecommuting programs26.
3.2.3 Perspective
Based on the American Community
Survey, an additional 3% of the work force may work at home by 2040. Although the literature offers mixed evidence
on the impact of telecommuting on travel, it is expected to help reduce commute
travel during peak hours. However, the
ability to telecommute may motivate workers to relocate farther away from
workplace in the long term. This will
increase commute distance on non-telecommuting days and may result in increases
in distance traveled by automobile.
Travel time savings from telecommuting will bring about
additional non-work travel, which offsets the benefits of telecommuting. Since non-work travel tends to occur closer
to home than commute trips, telecommuting is expected to reduce VMT slightly
(Choo, Mokhtarian et al. 2005). Because telecommuters’ activity space is closer
to home than to work on telecommuting days (Saxena and Mokhtarian 1997),
telecommuting will help ease traffic congestion on the freeways and around
employment centers even if the number of trips (including both commute and
non-work travel) is the same on telecommuting and non-telecommuting days.
Although coffee shops have
become a new workplace for many workers, they are not expected to materially
influence vehicular travel, similar to neighborhood telecenters. In particular, workers at neighborhood
telecenters tend to have a higher number of return home trips and other
non-work trips on telecommuting days and they also tend to shift from other
modes to driving alone (Balepur, Varma et al. 1998). The potential increases in engine cold starts
will further reduce the environmental benefits of telecommuting.
It is worth noting that ICT have made traditional “9-5” work
schedule and fixed locations obsolete.
People can work at home, at restaurants, while travelling and at any
time when it is convenient.
People can work remotely as well
as at primary office in a day. Therefore, not all the implications of
teleworking relate to transportation.
3.3 E-shopping
“Shopping online is about to
explode. Retailers of all types are expanding product offerings, adding
in-store pickup, free shipping and experimenting with social media. It’s
getting harder to tell pure play Internet retailers from the bricks and mortar
shops with online portals, and all of them are reinventing how we’ll shop online
in the future” (Heller 2011).
In 2000, retail sales of Ecommerce[16]
in the USA totaled about $27.5 billion, according to US Census E-commerce
Report. In 2014, the sales have
increased to $297.5 billion. The 10-fold
growth of E-commerce signifies its pervasive impacts on retail industries as
well as transportation.
3.3.1 The impacts of e-shopping on
transportation
Transportation planners are
interested in the changes that e-shopping will bring to transportation system.
In particular, planners tend to focus on the effects of e-shopping on
individuals’ activitytravel patterns. The potential of online buying to
substitute for traditional in-store shopping and reduce personal shopping
travel has important implications for travel demand management and congestion
mitigation. According to the 2001
National Household Transportation Survey (NHTS), on average shopping travel
accounted for 14.4% of annual VMT per household and 21.1% of annual vehicle
trips per household (Hu and Reuscher 2004).
Therefore, the growth of online buying could have the potential to
reduce traffic if it does replace physical shopping – substitution. On the other hand, if e-shopping induces new
shopping trips, it is likely to generate more personal travel to existing
transportation systems – complementarity.
What does the literature say on
the impact of e-shopping on traditional store shopping? Some descriptive studies offer mixed
outcomes. Cairns et al. (2004) report
that online shopping reduces at least one vehicular trip for 80% of 538 U.K.
Internet users polled by British Telecom.
However, Sim and Koi (2002) state that 88% of 175 Singapore online
buyers do not observe any influence on their travel to stores. Corpuz and Peachman (2003) show that 14% of
respondents in Sydney would have not made the purchase if online shopping were
not available and 19% would have made a special trip to stores. That is, online shopping not only induces
consumption but also replaces physical trips.
Several multivariate analyses
have been conducted to understand the relationships between online shopping and
store shopping. Using the 2000 San Francisco Bay Area Travel Survey, Ferrell
(2004, Ferrell 2005) employs two-step linear regression and structural equation
models, respectively, to examine the impacts of teleshopping on
shopping-related travel behavior. In the
two studies, he finds substitution, complementarity, and neutrality depending
on the dependent variables of interest.
Farag and colleagues conducted a series of studies in the Netherlands
and find that online shopping frequency is positively associated with store
shopping frequency, even after controlling for shopping attitudes and/or
demographics such as income (Farag, Schwanen et al. 2005, Farag, Krizek et al.
2006, Farag, Schwanen et al. 2007). A
complementary relationship is also found in Northern California (Circella and
Mokhtarian 2009), Israel (Rotem-Mindali 2010), Norway (Hjorthol 2009), and the
Twin Cities (Cao, Xu et al. 2012).
Freathy and Calderwood (2013) and Calderwood and Freathy (2014) find both complementary and substitution
effects, but they also state that online shopping has a limited impact on
shopping travel in the Scottish Isles. Hiselius, Rosqvist et al. (2015) also
conclude that there are few differences in trip frequency and travel distance
between frequent online shoppers and other shoppers. Although complementarity seems to dominate
the literature, the impact of the Internet on shopping is more complex than it
appears. By decomposing the shopping process of books and digital products, Cao
(2012) concludes that the Internet facilitates a hybrid shopping process: people use different shopping channels at
different shopping stages. For example,
an individual may become aware of a product in a store, search for product
information through a home computer, and then make a trip to the store to
acquire it. Using the 2009 National
Household Travel Survey (NHTS) data, Zhou and Wang (2014) find that the
relationships between online shopping and shopping trips are asymmetric: online
shopping encourages store shopping but the latter reduces the former.
A positive association between
online shopping and store shopping is often reported in the literature. This is not surprising because ICT gives
individuals many new motivations to engage in physical travel (Dal Fiore,
Mokhtarian et al. 2014). In the context
of shopping, Mokhtarian and Circella (2007) propose three mechanisms for such a
positive association. First, buying
online induces purchases for other related products such as accessories, which
may take place in stores (and conversely for shopping in stores). This represents a direct causal
influence. Second, Internet purchasing
eliminates travel time to and from stores and the time saved may be used for
other shopping-related activities and travel.
This is an indirect causal influence.
Third, the association is spurious, resulting from factors antecedent to
both online shopping and store shopping.
For example, women may buy both online and in stores more frequently
than men, and affluent people and those who enjoy shopping may have a high
demand for shopping through multiple channels.
Furthermore, online shopping enables consumers to fragment their shopping. For example, instead of buying all products
through a single trip, consumers may purchase the products through different
channels in multiple episodes. In this
way the ability to shop online may induce additional shopping trips to stores.
The relationships between online
buying and store shopping are complicated and far from being settled knowledge
(Rotem-Mindali and Weltevreden 2013).
Furthermore, the Internet allows users to search product information
online. This also increases store
shopping trips (Farag, Schwanen et al. 2007, Cao, Douma et al. 2010). Moreover, the rise of e-shopping means
increasing delivery trips to end consumers, which leads to the growth in
freight transport (See Chapter 8)
(Anderson, Chatterjee et al. 2003).
On the other hand, the
relationships between online shopping and store shopping may differ by product
type (Cao and Mokhtarian 2005). Product
attributes greatly affect the suitability for online shopping and hence the
potential substitution effect (Peterson, Balasubramanian et al. 1997). Peterson et al. (1997) argue that low-cost,
frequently-purchased, and physical products are more suitable for traditional
stores; low-cost, frequently-purchased, and informational products are more
likely to be purchased online; and high-cost, infrequently purchased goods can
be purchased through both traditional stores and Internet stores. E-shopping is likely to have a detrimental
impact on traditional retailers on digital products – music and books. For example, shares of Best Buy decreased
more than 30% during 2011; the decline in sales was due to fierce competition
from online vendors as well as Wal-Mart and Target (La Monica 2011); Borders,
the second-largest bookstore in the U.S. filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy
protection in February 2011.
3.3.2 Trend analysis
Applying the logistic growth
curve to the E-commerce data from 2000 to 2015, three different scenarios with
different saturation levels are presented in Figure 3.2. The low-saturation scenario assumes that
retail sales of E-commerce will eventually account for 10% of total retail
sales. The rationale for this scenario
is that although e-commerce is growing, its growth rate is slowing down during
the past several years. This rate is
optimistic because the share of E-commerce in total retail sales in China is
already at 10.7% (CNNIC 2014). The
high-saturation scenario assumes that the saturation rate is at 50%. E-shopping will not eliminate traditional
shopping because not all products are suitable for e-shopping and many people
consider shopping is an important leisure activity. Since “53 percent of
consumers would prefer to see, feel and touch a product before buying”[17],
the saturation level of e-commerce might reach about 50% of total retail
sales. This rate
In the low-saturation scenario,
the share of e-shopping will reach 90% of the saturation level (9%) in 2023. In
the medium-saturation scenario, the share of e-shopping will reach 90% of the
saturation level (27%) in 2037. In the high-saturation scenario, the share of
e-shopping will reach 90% of the saturation level (45%) in 2042. This implies that the peak impact of
e-shopping on traditional shopping is likely to occur within the time frame of
the next long-range transportation plan.
3.3.3 Perspectives
Though shopping travel has declined over the past decade (as
discussed above and in Chapter 8),
there is to date no persuasive causal evidence that online shopping is
responsible, and the degree to which it has the potential to significantly
reduce individuals’ shopping trips to stores in the future remains
uncertain. Most studies concluded a
complementarity effect of e-shopping on traditional store shopping (Andreev,
Salomon et al. 2010). Although a few
activity-based studies found that e-shopping tends to reduce shopping travel
and other leisure activities (Ferrell 2004, Ferrell 2005, Ding and Lu 2015),
activity diaries conducted for one day are not long enough to capture the whole
process of e-shopping, which can take days or even weeks to complete because of
its temporal fragmentation.
Because almost all existing studies are based on relatively
low shares (less than 10%) of ecommerce in total retail sales, it is less
certain about the relationships between e-shopping and store shopping when the
share grows much higher. However, since
ICT tends to have a dominant complementary effect on transportation in the long
run (Choo, Lee et al. 2007), it is not unreasonable to expect that the number
of shopping trips will grow or at least stay the same, whereas the delivery
trips and freight transport associated with e-shopping will definitely
grow. If the saturation rate of
e-commerce is at 30% or higher, the delivery traffic on local streets will
increase substantially. The bypass of
wholesalers and retailers in the network from manufacturers to consumers will
significantly change the operation patterns of freight transportation
(Anderson, Chatterjee et al. 2003).
The impacts should be considered in the next regional
transportation plans because e-shopping is expected to be close to saturation
before or around 2040.
3.4 Other Tele-activities and Travel
Andreev and colleagues (2010) reviewed about 100 studies on
tele-activities. The vast majority of
the studies are on telecommuting and teleshopping. Some studies focus on tele-banking,
teleleisure, and so on. Some studies
found that ICT tend to increase travel for leisure activities (Andreev, Salomon
et al. 2010). Limited evidence suggests
that telebanking and telemedicine tend to replace physical travel to
corresponding service locations (Andreev, Salomon et al. 2010). This may be because banking and seeing a
doctor are more of mandatory activities.
On the other hand, the time saved by telebanking and telemedicine may be
used for other indoor and/or outdoor activities.
Telemedicine is particularly
intriguing because of its potential to reduce travel during inconvenient
occasions such as midnight, weekend, and while working. On the other hand, telemedicine will not make
traditional office visits obsolete.
Telemedicine is more suitable to minor health problems and is an
alternative to some urgent care and primary care visits. It is particularly viable for specialty
service in rural areas where medical service is inadequate. It was projected that global telemedicine
market will be double from 2014 to 2020[18]. The penetration of telemedicine has many
barriers from the perspectives of doctors, patients, and insurance industries[19]. Further, it greatly depends on government
regulations and laws; it is limited or even prohibited in many states31.
Further, online schooling/training/conferencing has become
more and more popular. However, studies
on the relationships between these virtue activities and travel are
scarce. There is no rigorous inference
regarding their impacts on travel. For
example, teleconferencing enables people to “meet” without travel. On the other hand, it increases people’s
social network and also increase motivations to meet other people in person
(Button and Maggi 1995). The net effect
is unclear. Social travel has declined
in the past decade, however.
Bandwidth can be a barrier for
some tele-activities such as telemedicine and tele-learning, particularly in
rural areas where broadband service remains limited. The inevitable improvement in service quality
will encourage those in remote areas to engage in virtue activities. This will improve their access to jobs and
services and reduce their long-distance travel.
3.5 Summary of ICT and travel
Since the introduction of ICT,
researchers have examined their impact on transportation system. Early studies have extensively explored the
relationships between telecommuting and travel and estimated the aggregate impact
of telecommuting on transportation system.
As e-shopping proliferated in the 2000s, geographers and transportation
planners have investigated the influences of e-shopping on traditional store
shopping and related travel behavior.
Overall, the studies on telecommuting and e-shopping dominate the
literature on the connections between ICT and travel; a few studies started to
explore online banking, telemedicine, and virtual leisure activities.
The literature on telecommuting and e-shopping offers mixed
evidence on the impacts of ICT on travel. For telecommuting, the key findings
include the following:
Telecommuting
reduces commute travel during peak hours as well as non-peak hours;
Telecommuting enables commuters to move
farther away from their employment location and become auto-dependent;
Telecommuting
increases non-work travel, which takes place mostly close to home;
Telecommuting reduces VMT slightly but
it helps mitigate the growth of congestion on freeways;
Telecommuting is likely to influence
the travel of other household members but concrete evidence is limited;
Working
at informal sites such as coffee shops will not materially reduce VMT.
For e-shopping, the literature shows that
Online searching is positively
associated with store shopping (people who buy online also buy in person
more);
Studies are mixed on whether e-shopping
reduces travel to stores and other leisure activities in the short term;
E-shopping for now digital products
(books, records, videos) has already changed retail patterns and shopping
travel behavior;
Online
buying increases delivery traffic and freight transportation;
Existing
studies are based on the small share of e-shopping in retail industries. If its share is large enough to change the
distribution of commercial land uses in the region, e-shopping will have a
profound effect on shopping-related travel.
From the transportation
perspective, a goal behind the drive to promote ICT is to reduce travel. Although ICT are often promoted as a virtual
alternative to physical travel, transportation planners should be realistic
about the relationships between ICT and travel:
although the short term effect of ICT on travel may be substitution, in
the long term, travel demand has historically grown as ICT demand increases
(Choo, Lee et al. 2007, Choo and Mokhtarian 2007, Andreev, Salomon et al.
2010). The extent to which that relationship holds in the future is an open
question, as ICT becomes higher and higher quality.
Based on an extensive analysis of the literature, Mokhtarian
(2009) offers twelve reasons for the paradoxical results:
1.
“Not all activities have an ICT counterpart”.
For example, activities such as gardening and repairing need workers to be at
specific locations.
2.
“Even when an ICT alternative exists in theory,
it may not be practically feasible”. For
example, technology may not be available at certain time or certain areas.
3.
“Even when feasible, ICT is not always a
desirable substitute”. For example, some people consider shopping an important
leisure activity and they do not want to entirely eliminate it.
4.
“Travel carries a positive utility”. Sometimes,
people travel for its own sake, such as the Sunday drive, jogging, or just
getting out of the house.
5.
“Not all uses of ICT constitute a replacement of
travel”. For example, if teleconferencing were not available, people may not
hold a meeting at all. That is, technology induces demand.
6.
“ICT saves time and/or money for other
activities”. For example, if an individual saves travel time because of working
at home, she may travel for other purposes within her travel time budget.
7.
“ICT permits travel to be sold more cheaply”.
For example, the Internet makes comparable shopping for air tickets easier and
hence lowers the cost of travel for consumers.
8.
“ICT increases the efficiency of the
transportation system, making travel more attractive”. For example, the
implementation of ramp metering improves traffic flow on the freeway and hence
makes long-distance commuting more desirable than before.
9.
“Personal ICT use can increase the productivity
and/or enjoyment of travel time”. For example, watching iPad while travelling
reduces the disutility of travel and hence the subjective value of travel time
is not all wasteful (see Chapter 2).
10.
“ICT directly stimulates additional travel”. For
example, an instant message or use of mobile phone may motivate an individual
to visit certain place and increase car use (Hjorthol 2008).
11.
“ICT is an engine driving the increasing
globalization of commerce”. The globalization of commerce promoted by ICT
induces additional travel such as freight transport from overseas and business
travel among different countries.
12.
“ICT facilitates shifts to more decentralized
and lower-density land use patterns”. For example, the ability to telecommute
may enable individuals to move to a distant suburban neighborhood and
suburbanites tend to travel more than urban residents. Therefore, ICT indirectly increases travel
(albeit off-peak).
On the other hand, Mokhtarian offers four scenarios that ICT
has the potential to reduce travel.
ICT sometimes directly
substitutes for travel. For example,
telecommuting slightly reduce VMT (Choo, Mokhtarian et al. 2005). “ICT consumes
time (and/or money) that might otherwise have been spent traveling”. For example, online shopping reduces
out-of-home leisure activities (Ding and Lu 2015). “When travel becomes more costly, difficult,
or dangerous, ICT substitution will increase”.
For example, when there is a weather event, like a blizzard or
hurricane, telecommuting becomes attractive.
Finally, ICT makes car-sharing more convenient. Without mobile applications, the amount of
shared ride will reduce significantly.
Overall, although the promotion of ICT aims to reduce
travel, it simultaneously induces new travel.
The net effect of
further proliferation of these technologies remains ambiguous.
Chapter 4: Mobility-as-a-Service
For physical (rather than virtual) objects, one person's use
prevents someone else's use. Many physical objects are not fully utilized by
their owners. Cars, for instance, typically remain unused 22 or 23 out of 24
hours in the day. The basic idea of collaborative consumption is that things
can be shared rather than individually owned (e.g., one rents hotel rooms and
cars rather than buying condos and vehicles when on travel; it is now common to
rent music, videos, and books), increasing economic efficiency.
Previously cars, taxis, and hotel rooms were rented from
companies which could achieve large economies of scale, but in a way that was
inconvenient for customers. Now it is possible to rent couches and cars and
rides from individuals with excess capacity at the push of a button through an
app. The degree to which economies of scale trump the network effects of
distributed suppliers awaits to be seen. We roll out three dimensions of
sharing—cars, rides, bikes—that have emerging implications for transport.
4.1 Sharing Cars
"Carsharing" is a marketing term for modern car
rental services. People are "sharing" the car just as they share a
hotel room — by paying a third party and using it at separate times.[20]
In most US carsharing services, the ownership is by a private for-profit
company (a few are non-profits); the service is not owned by its members. They
employ mobile information technologies to avoid the repetitive contract
negotiations that were once common when one wanted to rent a multi-thousand
dollar vehicle from a multi-national corporation.
There are notable differences between traditional and modern
car rental. First, the car is reserved via a website (or more recently, a
smart-phone app) and unlocked via a special member card or the phone itself, no
real-time intervening labor is required between you and the car. Second, the newest
of these services allows you to pick up and drop off your car at any legal
on-street parking space, no longer only at special stations or locations (this
model is used by Car2Go in Minneapolis and Saint Paul).[21]
Third, the rentals can be by the number of minutes, rather than days, so cars
may be less expensive to rent for a short trip.
In the US the first break-out company in this sector was
Zipcar,[22]
which adopted at the station-based model widely used in Europe[23],
requiring cars to be returned to their rental station. The problems with
station-based carsharing vs. the Car2Go models are several. First the stations
may be inconvenient. Second the user has to know exactly how long is the trip,
since overage charges are significant (some $50). From the station-based
carsharing company’s perspective, with such a thin fleet of vehicles, the
overage charge is essential to guarantee the car will be available for the next
renter, but to avoid being late, the renter had to reserve the car for a longer
time period than actual used. Third, the technology is a bit wonky, leading to
risk of having no car available at all.
Zipcar went public in 2011 with 8,000 cars, 500,000 members
and $186 million in revenue. Never profitable, it was acquired by Avis in 2013
at about one-third its 2011 market capitalization.
Car2Go (and others) all strive for various improvements on the
same theme, most notably the ability to park anywhere rather than at a station.36
New economic models include RelayRides, which allow individuals to rent their
own car, and is perhaps best suited to airports where cars are otherwise parked
for a long time.
Like most automakers, BMW is entering the carsharing market
with DriveNow. Ian Robertson with the company says “As a mobility provider, the
BMW Group is not simply an automobile manufacturer”.37 BMW also
combines carsharing with leases, so for instance, you can lease a small EV
during the week and get access to a larger vehicle on the weekend.
The importance of carsharing is not as a replacement for
rental cars, which are still standard in their traditional market of airports
and auto replacement during servicing — though that may change as well.
Carsharing also is not cost-effective as a replacement for daily commuting
trips. However if you walk, bike, or take transit to work, it might be good to
replace owning a car, or second car, for the occasional (say weekly) trips that
are too far to practically walk or bike, and too inconvenient to use a transit
system that serves downtown well and little else. In crowded urban areas where
paying for parking at your home is a real financial burden, carsharing is more
promising than most of America where parking is practically free.
36 Car2Go, a
newer service, works better for users. Some 535 cars are deployed throughout
Minneapolis and St. Paul, so a user can reserve a car (no more than 30 minutes
in advance) within walking distance. The app will show directions to the car.
Once you enter the car, find the
key, turn the ignition, fill out a brief survey on car quality, and off you go.
Unlike Zipcar, Car2Go bills by the minute. When you are done, you check out
from the car.
Car2Go uses Smart Fortwo vehicles,
which are the smallest and least expensive commercially available road-worthy
vehicles in the US. The Smart Fortwo,
despite being a unit of Daimler, best known for the Mercedes Benz, is not a
luxury vehicle.
37 Vijayenthiran,
Viknesh (2011-03-24) “BMW Is No Longer Just An Automaker, It’s A Mobility
Provider.” Motor Authority http://www.motorauthority.com/news/1057282_bmw-is-no-longer-just-an-automaker-its-a-mobility-provider
Figure 4.1: North American Carsharing
Growth
The car-shedding question remains: How many households will
surrender a second (or first) car for the occasional trip?[24]
Is the market thick enough that the likelihood of finding a car nearby is high
enough that it is reliable enough to use? With Car2Go there is no guarantee
there will be a car within walking distance. While the service tries to rebalance
their fleet if it gets out of whack (for instance, all the cars are in St. Paul
and all the demand is in Minneapolis), this is not free for them, nor does it
occur instantaneously. This is where other services (taxi, transport network
companies, transit) come in as backups. This is also where autonomous vehicles
can be important.
Nevertheless, people don't want to think about every
transaction, and if they are charged per use, obviously would use less, and
will be less happy, and more determined to get a car of their own to avoid
transaction costs. Cars have costs of their own, but they are less frequent and
less obvious. If the charges are invisible though, people may not think about
them. Just as information technology
went from terminals and mainframes to personal computers, and internet cafes to
internet at home, transport technology went from trains and transit to private
transport once we could afford it. The cost savings will have to be
considerable for most people to want to go back. But habits are easier to form
in the young. An urban college student who joins Car2Go may keep it after they
graduate if they remain city-bound.
The best market for Car2Go may be the urban hipster: with
enough money to afford, enough transit to get to work and back with minimum
hassle, enough childlessness to have a simple schedule, enough desire to signal
greenness to avoid owning a car, but enough sense and desire for dates in the
country or trips to Ikea to recognize the occasional need.
Figure 8.1 shows trends on carsharing in North America. It is
not clear where market saturation is, and whether the dip in 2015 is just a
data issue or indicative that perhaps ridesharing is stealing some carsharing
thunder. Notably carsharing company Shift shuttered in Las Vegas in mid-2015.[25]
4.2 Sharing Rides
Just as carsharing refers to modern car rental services,
"ridesharing" is a marketing term for modern taxi services, and
providers like to think of themselves as “transportation network companies.”[26]
You might have thought ridesharing was the same as car-pooling. And it is, if
you think of modern "ridesharing" drivers as your friends giving you
a lift (or in the name of one company a Lyft), not for money, but for a
voluntary ‘donation’. Whether this attempt to skirt the rules and regulations
of taxis succeeds is a battle to be fought out in thousands of local markets
globally. In markets where an agreement has been reached, the ‘donation’
results in an actual charge and the process—enabled by smartphones—is taking
off.41
The car you get with Lyft (or UberX) is the driver's
personal car, not a fleet vehicle.
Lyft is in many ways simply an app with a back-end (rather,
"cloud-based") dispatch service. They claim to be a "transport
network company whose mobile-phone application facilitates peer-to-peer
ridesharing by enabling passengers who need a ride to request one from drivers
who have a car." They insist the drivers are independent (as are the
riders). The difference between this and a taxi dispatcher is thin. An internet
definition of a taxi is "a car licensed to transport passengers in return
for payment of a fare, usually fitted with a taximeter." So for taxicabs,
the arrangement between the rider and the passenger is mediated by the government
(which licenses the vehicles).
Are Lyft drivers licensed to transport passengers for payment?
This is a major point of contention. They are licensed drivers, and any
licensed driver (above a certain age and level of experience) is eligible to
carry passengers. The cars are private cars (at least sometimes) though that is
little different than how taxis operate in other parts of the world. Many
Singaporean taxi drivers will take fares when going between where they are
going anyway, but otherwise treat the taxis as a personal vehicle.
Lyft now offers jitney (shared taxi, dollar van, informal
transport) type services, dubbed Lyft Line in selected markets. (Uber has the
similar UberPool) These serve either one
pickup going to multiple destinations, or multiple pickups going to one
destination, or multiple origins to multiple destinations, and compete with
both taxi and public transit. (Though it would not be exactly fixed routes, one
could imagine regular runs with a known coterie of passengers). This is at a lower
rate. While these services are at the time of this writing only in San
Francisco and New York, Lyft now claims that Lyft Line comprises 50% of Lyft's
rides in San Francisco and 30% in New York.42 (Not all of Lyft Line
customers wind up in a shared ride, they just indicate a willingness to share
in exchange for a lower fare, and get the lower fare regardless of whether
another passenger can be found). The ease of making ride requests and payments
is what drives many customers to choose Uber or Lyft over traditional taxis.
41 How does
Lyft (or any other Transportation Network Company) work? From the perspective
of the user (1 and 2 are one-time) the following is the sequence:
1.
Download the App.
2.
Enter the required info
3.
Open the App and summon a Ride.
4.
Get in the Lyft vehicle when it arrives (the driver
will usually call to confirm pickup location/time), it has a small mustache in
the window.
5.
Tell the Driver the Destination — You can enter this in
the app as well, though it doesn't affect who picks you up (yet) apparently.
This is an opportunity for efficiency, as drivers, for instance, may be happy
to go towards their home near the end of a shift, but not away. On the other
hand, that might lead to too few drivers "bidding" on prospective
customers. 6. Ride
7.
Get out of the Car.
8.
Check App to rate the driver. Payment is automatic
unless you want to change your payment.
42 Bregman, Susan (2015-04-23) Uber and Lyft
claim carpooling success.
TheTransitWire.com. http://www.thetransitwire.com/2015/04/23/uber-lyft-claim-carpooling-success/
Differentiating status and class is another important element.
Users are hip enough and wealthy enough to use the new technology and not have
to sit where others from other classes have sat before. As these services
become widespread, humans will undoubtedly develop new forms of elitism.
Venture capitalists believe these will be very successful
companies. Uber has been valued at over $50 Billion. There are however many
competitors (including of course Lyft, as well as BlaBlaCar, Didi Kuaidi,[27]
Gett, Curb, Hailo, Blacklane, Sidecar, Zimride, iHail, and Flywheel, among
others) and the stickiness of riders and drivers to any particular company is
weak and their limited advantages to larger services over smaller ones.[28] The competition from the new entrants has
driven taxi companies to step up their game, a number of the services listed
are better interfaces to traditional taxi. Drivers are already simultaneously
on multiple networks, so the expected pickup time doesn’t vary much from one
app to another. Waze, a subsidiary of Google, is testing a true peer-to-peer,
realtime, no payment ride-sharing service.
Shuddle, KangaDo, and HopSkipDrive are trying to be the “Uber for kids”.[29] SheTaxis aims to be an “Uber for Women.”[30]
4.3 Sharing Bikes
A recent popular internet meme[31]
noted that in Europe, bicycles were outselling cars.[32] The National Bicycle Dealers Association
(NBDA) reports[33]
annual bike sales on the order of 18.7 million for 2012. In contrast, US car
sales are on the order of 8 million, along with another 8 million light trucks.
So where are all these bikes, why are they not seen more on roads
everyday?
Many of the bikes sold annually are for children (5.7 million
of the 18.7 million are below 20 inches wheel (50 cm)), but even so, 13 million
are 20 inch and above wheel size, and 13 million is still much bigger than 8
million cars (and near 16 million light vehicles, note also that many light
vehicles are not for personal use). Even just inspecting specialty bike shops,
which sell at the higher end, that's nearly 3.1 million bikes per year, which
while less than cars, is still a pretty big number.
Yet, the volume of trips by bike and certainly miles by bike
are much lower than by car and are not poised to overtake in the US. We don't
even see 3.1 million bike commutes daily in the US (The American Community
Survey reports (undoubtedly an under-report, [34]
but still a small share) 865,000), so these are more likely for recreational
than utilitarian purposes.
Another reason for this statistic is that bikes don't last
as long as cars.[35]
So lack of bikes does not seem to be a problem, but bikes
where you want them may be. If I didn't take my bike to work, I can't use my
bike for a lunchtime ride at work. If I am a tourist, I probably didn't bring a
bike with me. Wouldn't it be great to just get a bike when and where I want it,
and abandon it there at the end of the trip. Well, it is not quite modern
carsharing, but widely dispersed bike stations make this closer to possible. As
shown in Figure 8.2, bike sharing systems have grown in many cities worldwide.
Bikesharing, the modern version of bike rentals, (just as
carsharing is the modern version of car rental) has both a membership and per-use
model. A member signs up online, gets an electronic key in the mail, and can
visit a bikeshare station in their system and simply insert a key in the slot
next to the bike they want, and pull it out, and remove the bike. They then
have, say, 60 minutes to use the bike before it needs to be returned to a
station (any station, not just the one it was borrowed from). A one-time user
has to insert a credit card. These measures ensure the bicycles are returned
and not found in the bottom of a nearby river, the sad outcome of early free
bikesharing schemes. The bikes, while functional, are unlikely to be a model a
regular bicyclist would purchase. They are especially heavy, and only 3-speed,
so the risk of theft is relatively low.
Bikesharing is about transport as much as active recreation,
and a way of connecting these two things.
Figure 4.2: Growth of Bike Sharing Systems
Globally
The number of systems may be leveling off. Maturation in the
number of systems is a good thing in many respects. A next step, however, is to
stop adding new systems in favor of increasing the services of existing
systems, inter-connecting and inter-operating (maybe even consolidating some).
A related aim is broadening the subscriptions globally, so that memberships can
be used on any system in the world.[36]
Nice Ride Minnesota, the largest bikesharing system in the
state, has shown continuous growth from 2010 through 2015, as shown in Figures
4.3 and 4.4.[37]
This is complemented by a significant increase in those years in
bicycle-dedicated infrastructure, including separated bike-lanes. More bike
traffic is expected to have a safety-in-numbers property that crash rates per
bicyclist will decline with an increase in the number of bicycles.
Bikesharing can function as an extender of transit service, as
people take transit, transfer to a bikeshare to reach a final destination (or
for recreation), and to return to the transit stop. This requires a station at
the destination end, or the destination to be short duration. Future
bikesharing need not be be station-based (with GPS and smart-phone apps),
though such as system has yet to be deployed in Minnesota. So there are
continued opportunities for growth with the current technological arrangements.
Figure 4.3: NiceRide’s Service Area
continues to grow (source NiceRide MN, 2015)
4.4 The Future of Sharing: Cloud Commuting
For communities where densities are relatively low, incomes
high, and thus taxis scarce, the most reliable strategy for timely
point-to-point transport is for people to maintain personal transport close at
hand. Cars and bikes, which they own, are parked at their homes, workplaces, or
other destinations. But with more widespread use of information technologies,
ownership and possession are no longer necessary prerequisites for on-demand
mobility. Widely called the "sharing economy" or "collaborative
consumption", its manifestations in transport: "carsharing" and
"ridesharing" are viable if not widespread. Couple these technologies with autonomous
vehicles discussed Chapter 1, and
one arrives at "cloud commuting" — the convergence of ridesharing,
carsharing, and autonomous vehicles.[38]
Figure 4.4: NiceRide’s Annual Revenue
continues to grow (source NiceRide MN, 2015)
More formally, this range of options can be termed
Mobility-as-a-Service (MaaS). While nascent today, clearly big players are
placing big bets that this will be a big change in how people travel. It is
this which explains Uber’s high market valuation. A vehicle from a giant pool of autonomous
cars operated by organizations based "in the cloud" would be
dispatched to a customer on-demand and in short order, and then would deliver
the customer to her destination (be it work or otherwise) before moving on to the
next customer. Even more efficiently, it might pick-up or drop-off some
additional passengers along the way and may offer customer specific features.[39]
[40]
We quickly run down implications as MaaS emerges.
Smaller, more modern fleet. The
customer benefits by not tying up her capital in vehicles, nor having to worry
about maintaining or fueling vehicles. The fleet is used more efficiently, each
vehicle would operate at least 2 times (and as much as 10 times) more distance
per year than current vehicles, so the fleet would turnover faster and stay
more modern.
Fewer vehicles overall would be needed at a given time. It is
likely customers would need to pay for this service either as a subscription or
a per-use basis. Advertising might offset some costs, but probably not cover
them. However retail stores (if they survive) might subsidize transport, as
might employers, as benefits for customers or staff.
Coverage, logistics. Like
traditional fixed-route transit, MaaS will function better in urban areas than
rural areas. Response time will be shorter (potentially faster than getting a
parked car); size and variety of the vehicle pool will be greater; parking in
high value areas becomes less troublesome. MaaS will also fit better for nonwork
rather than work trips, as the regularity of work increases the value of either
vehicle ownership or regularly using micro- or macro-transit versus renting by
the trip.
Autonomy solves the localness problem facing existing
carsharing services, since the cars come to you. Like current bike sharing
systems, there would need to be load balancing features, so the cars were
pre-dispatched to areas of anticipated demand, and maybe coordinated carpooling
at peak times.
Costs. Automation
also structurally transforms the labor costs of ridesharing services.[41]
It allows a variety of vehicles to serve customers, rather than a single,
literally least common denominator model. An interesting aspect of this from
the perspective of travel demand is that with MaaS, people will probably pay by
the trip, either directly, or through choosing the right plan of service
roughly proportional to use. While the average cost of car ownership, now a
quite significant share of household expenses, goes to zero for those who join this
system, the out-of-pocket marginal cost per trip rises quite significantly. The
implication is fewer trips for people give up on vehicle ownership. People
paying by the minute or the mile will want to reduce trip distances.
Electrification.
Autonomous and shared vehicles will interact with electrification discussed in Chapter 6. A rental service of
self-driving autonomous vehicles, that are ordered on-demand may provide you a
fully charged electric vehicle for your trip. Much like the Pony Express, which
swapped horses rather than requiring riders to wait for their own horse to
rest, the service may provide a replacement vehicle mid-trip rather than
requiring you to wait around to charge your vehicle.[42] There is no requirement that cloud-based,
self-driving vehicles be electric, but as cars get smarter they should be able
to charge themselves, alleviating some of the concerns associated with EVs.
Street Design. Streets designs
will need to accommodate pick-up and drop-off as a major feature, so curb space
will need to be re-arranged so people know where to meet their car (and vice
versa), so they don’t get into the wrong white Prius. While we lose the need for parking, we might
think of channelizing roads more like airports or multi-way boulevards than the
monolithic pavement they are today.
4.5 The Future of Travel Demand and Where We Live: The Up Scenario
In Chapter 1 on
Autonomous Vehicles, we described the “Out Scenario”. Privately held
autonomous vehicles which are faster and reduce the cognitive burden on drivers
will increase suburbanization. In contrast, MaaS eliminates the fixed cost of
transportation, and exchanges it for a higher per cost trip. Logically, if the
time or money cost per trip rises, there should be fewer and shorter trips, or reduced demand.
The share of ownership versus MaaS is thus an important
predictor of travel demand in the coming years.
Up: Less vehicle
ownership with increased use of MaaS in cities, raising the value of cities.
Driverless cars which can be summoned on demand allow people to avoid vehicle
ownership altogether. This will reduce vehicle travel, as people will pay more
to rent by the minute than they do when they own. Since total expenditures on
transport are saved, additional funds are available to pay for rent in cities,
and more trips are by walk, bike, and transit. People who seek the set of urban
amenities (entertainment, restaurants, a larger dating pool) will find these
amenities increasing in response to the population. The greater value in cities
with the new more convenient technology leads to more and taller development.
(Hence the use of the word “Up”.)
A direct knock-on effect of the “Up” Scenario is that it will
transform the need for parking. It will also means vehicular dead-heading (cars
driving without any occupants to their next call), a phenomenon we now have
with transit and rail, though even those vehicles usually have drivers.
At the more local, urban level, the Mobility-as-a-Service
model implies spaces now devoted to cars can be repurposed—everything from
street space to buildings. Garages turn to accessory dwelling units. Gas
stations and parking lots to anything with a "higher and better use".
Autonomous vehicles can drop off their passenger at the front door, and then
park themselves in far less space than drivers currently require (or move on to
their next passenger), and that space need not be so close to the most valuable
urban areas. On-street parking is not needed at all, one more aspect of roadspace
reconfiguration.
As David King says
“Redeveloping surface parking may be the single biggest challenge facing US
cities, but is also a rare opportunity for cities and many suburbs to rebuild
themselves fairly easily and quickly.”
4.6 Discussion
While we might think of “Up” and “Out” (described in Chapter 1) as contrasting scenarios,
they are not exclusive. More people living in the suburbs or exurbs does not
mean fewer people live in cities, so long as there are more people
overall. We expect more growth will be
either central or exurban, and less in existing low-density suburbs which
cannot effective offer MaaS nor fully exploit the wide open spaces of the
exurbs.
The model of vehicle ownership is being challenged with
alternative ways of providing transportation services enabled by mobile
telecommunications. Broadly these Mobility-as-a-service (MaaS) technologies can
up-end the current model of transportation ownership. Enabled by technologies
such as social networks with known identities, real-time ride matching, excess
seat capacity in passenger vehicle fleet, to be successful requires critical
mass. The full extent of the markets for these services is not yet clear. There
are implications for transit, which might perceive MaaS as poaching of
customers.
We posit that paying for trips by marginal rather than average
cost will reduce number of trips and the availability of such services will
reduce number owned vehicles. Social relationships will also change with these
new technologies. “Sharing” models
include: Car Sharing/Rental (e.g. Car2Go, ZipCar, HourCar, Enterprise Car
Sharing), Peer-to-Peer Car Sharing (e.g. Relay Rides), and Bike Sharing/Rental
(e.g. NiceRide). “Ridesharing” Transportation Network Companies include services
like Lyft and UberX, but are also associated with the changing nature of taxi
services. Fully dynamic ridesharing (peer-to-peer transportation) is the modern
phone-driven analog of hitchhiking.
Sharing—be it cars, bikes, boats or information—has strong
network effects driven by convenience (a characteristic the time-starved seem
particularly mindful of). But, macro versus micro transit discussions in the
following chapter bring up matters of economies of scale versus economies of
scope. There’s a role for both.
For example, one is more likely to use carsharing if more
neighbors use it, since that makes it more likely there will be a car in front
of one's house, workplace, or wherever, when it is desired. Reducing vehicle
access time from 10 minutes to 5 minutes, or 5 minutes to 2 minutes is
significant, especially when most trips are only 20 minutes long. As with any
social network, it is not clear in advance which if any will take off. As with
many networks, there needs to be a large up-front capital investment. But
unlike transit systems, carsharing is dealing mostly with mobile capital. If
the program doesn't work in place A, cars can be redeployed to place B, or at
worst, sold in a used car lot. Further the programs are privately funded, which
is more suited to innovation and adaptation, and accepting of failure, than
publicly funded transit agencies.
The Car2Go model has not yet put in enough capital, nor has
enough demand, so there is a car waiting on every block. To do so is no small
step, and may require automation.[43]
The economics and environmental benefits [44]
of renting rather than owning are clear, but the sociology and the the role of
regulation[45]
remain unclear. People willingly use
hotel rooms, or bikes, or library books that have been used by others before,
but not, typically, cars. How do cars get transformed from an owned good to a
rented service? In part this is generational. If you have never owned a car,
new habits can be formed. But that type of change is very slow, perhaps as slow
as generational shift. Early adopters and the carless may be quick to join.
Some/many/most Americans use their cars often enough, in places remote enough,
or customize their cars sufficiently that MaaS will not be advantageous in most
circumstances. The question is: What is the winning fraction?
We are hesitant to give an answer.
Loosely, environments which are currently dominated by
multi-family living (apartments) are more likely to be places where
Mobility-as-a-Service succeeds. Densities are higher, enabling various types of
shared services to have shorter response times, and making land values higher
so car storage is more expensive.
Nationally 35% of the US population are renters and 14% are
apartment dwellers. In Minnesota only 11% of the population are apartment
dwellers.[46]
To be clear today, not all apartment dwellers are transit riders or walk to
work (about 20% do), and not all single-family dwellers use the automobile to
get to work (though 96% do). Any change from a vehicle ownership-dominated to a
MaaS regime will take decades, and likely be slower than the introduction of
automation in the first place.
Chapter 5: Quantified Self and Quantified Networks
5.1 Introduction
There are now sensors measuring, tracking, and reporting
travelers’ location, pollution, noise, travel cost [e.g. in-vehicle taxi
meters], health, calories, and so on. As people are more interested in
self-tracking their daily behaviors (i.e., the increasingly popular Quantified
Self movement), transportation agencies have a new wealth of data that can
monitor the movement of people and vehicles across networks. These will enable
advanced traffic, air quality, and new security monitoring systems, among other
uses. How can agencies exploit these data? How will the “quantified self” and
“quantified networks” interact?
To explore answers to these questions, I first review
existing smartphone-based mobility sensing and quantification apps. Much of the
Quantified Self Movement is associated with the advance of the smartphone
technology. Innovative mobility apps have the power to transform the
relationship between transportation networks and travelers. The Future of
Transportation series produced by CityLab (formerly The Atlantic Cities) has
concluded that the smart phone is the most important transportation innovation
of the decade. There has been an
explosion of mobility apps and interfaces (e.g., RideScout, Google Maps, OMG Transit,
Waze, and Uber) that help people to make more informed mode and route
decisions. These apps offer functionalities ranging from trip planning and
navigation, to locating an approaching bus or for-hire vehicle. Of these apps,
this report focuses on apps that are specifically designed for travel data
collection (i.e., sensing and quantification). Besides reviewing existing
smartphone-based mobility sensing and quantification apps, this report
discusses the potential application of these apps in travel behavior
intervention and mobility management, followed by discussing potential areas
for future research when it comes to possible integrations between Quantified
Self and Quantified Networks technologies.
5.2 Smartphone-Based Mobility Sensing and Quantification Apps
Deriving travel information from mobility sensing data
(especially location sensing data) involves significant processing due to the
large amounts of data produced by GPS units/loggers or smartphones over
time. Based on the current literature
(Flamm & Kaufmann, 2007; Gong et al., 2014; Schuessler & Axhausen,
2009; Tsui & Shalaby, 2006; Wan & Lin, 2013), Figure 5.1 overviews the
steps when using GPS sensing data (either smartphone-based or non-smartphone
based) to identify and quantify travel characteristics. In general, the selection
of data filtration techniques depends greatly on the detail of the analysis to
be conducted and the quality of GPS data being used. Speed, distance, and time
were the most commonly used data filters. For activity/ trip identification,
the use of speed, time, and spatial density were amongst the most common
methods used. While studies used different methods for mode detection, only
Zheng et al. (2008) compared the detection capabilities of different models and
concluded that decision tree models outperformed others. Trip purpose detection
was found to rely heavily on the availability of accurate geographic
information (land use or points of interest data), the quality of which varies
from place to place.
Figure 5.1: Major Quantification Steps for
Analyzing Mobility Sensing Data
The steps illustrated in Figure 5.1 formed the foundation
for data processing algorithms in the smartphone mobility sensing and
quantification apps listed below:
The earliest smart phone app for
travel data collection is the MoALS system developed by Itsubo and Hato in
2006, requiring users to input the start time, destination and mode of trips;
it records GPS data in the background (Itsubo and Hato, 2006). The data
collected by the app is transmitted to a server and can be displayed on a
website. Users are also required to login to the website every day and confirm
the data collected by the app.
TRAC-IT is a smartphone app
developed by the University of South Florida to better understand household
travel behaviors and provide feedbacks to users (Winters et al, 2008). TRAC-IT
has two modes to collect travel data: It either logs GPS data continuously in
the background or allows users to initiate and terminate data logging for a
trip. Meanwhile, the app asks users to register trips and provide information
on attributes that cannot be extracted directly from GPS data. For example, the
app asks users questions about trip purposes and trip modes. After trip-related
information is collected, it transmits the collected data to a remote server
for data processing and retrieves travel advisory feedbacks from the server.
CycleTracks is an app developed by
the San Francisco County Transportation Authority (SFCTA) to collect bicycle
use data in the area. It utilizes the GPS sensor in smartphones to record
information on users' bicycle routes and times, and displays their rides on
maps. The app allows users to register bicycle trips, initiate GPS tracking,
and specify the trip purpose of each bicycle trip (SFCTA, 2015).
Future
Mobility Survey (FMS) is a smartphone based travel survey mainly deployed in
Singapore as a part of the nationwide Singaporean Household Interview Travel
Survey (HITS). To minimize user’s burden, the app is only used to collect
spatiotemporal information of travels while providing a web interface to
collect travel attribute data such as trip purposes, trip modes and trip
satisfaction. In addition, the web interface is also used as a portal for users
to input demographic information, review travel data and provide feedbacks
(Cottrill et al., 2013).
Moves is a commercial app developed
by ProtoGeo to collect all-day non-motorized travel (including walking, running
and cycling) data on smartphones. It logs GPS and accelerometer data
continuously, and automatically identifies trips and non-motorized modes used
in any of the trips. The app also allows users to tag activity locations using
three location types (home, work, or school) or place names available from
Foursquare API (https://developer.foursquare.com/). In addition, Moves has a
pedometer function that counts the daily number of steps that users take and
calculates daily calories burned (ProtoGeo, 2013).
ATLAS, standing for “Advanced Travel
Logging Application for Smartphones”, is an application designed specifically
for collecting travel data by the University of Queensland (Safi et al., 2013).
Its goal is to provide a user-friendly and convenient interface for users to
record travel data with minimum burden and maximum accuracy. The app provides
functions to record location data from the GPS sensor and trip attribute data
such as purposes and modes. It requires users to initiate and terminate the
tracking of each trip. Besides, it also collects basic socio-demographic
information such as age, gender and car ownership on the smartphone. In a later
study, ATLAS was utilized in a Smartphone-based Individual Travel Survey System
(SITSS), which was deployed as a part of the national household travel survey
of New Zealand (Safi et al., 2015). In SITSS, it was developed to be a two-step
data collection approach during which the app first logs GPS data continuously
and then invites participants to record their travels at the end of each day.
The app automatically detects movements longer than 400m and starts the travel
recording; it stops recording automatically when the device becomes stationary
for longer than 360 seconds.
CONNECT is an apps developed by Ghent
University to collect travel data. It provides functions for users to register
trips, initiate GPS and accelerometer tracking, and specify trip
characteristics. It also allows automatic triggering of specific surveys based
upon user input. For example, questions related to bicycle trips pop up when
users register such trips (Vlassenroot et al., 2014).
Quantified Traveler (QT) developed by
the University of California, Berkeley is aiming to record travel data and
provide travel suggestions that aim to trigger more sustainable travel
behaviors while satisfying travelers’ preferences (Jariyasunant, et al., 2015).
The QT logs GPS and accelerometer data continuously in the background,
transmits location and accelerometer data to a server in the cloud for post
processing, and periodically requests the user to access feedbacks through a
website that displays post-processing results from the server, including travel
cost and calculated footprints resulted from a user’s travel: the calories
burnt and CO2 spent traveling.
SmarTrAC is an app developed by the
University of Minnesota based on a previous app UbiActive (Fan et al., 2012).
It logs GPS and accelerometer data in the background, and automatically
identifies trips, as well as travel modes and trip purposes. The app provides
users immediate read and write access to results from real-time detection of
travel modes and activity types. The app also allows users to add additional
details about their activities and trips, such as companion information and
their emotional experience. SmarTrAC distinguishes itself from other apps in
three aspects: first, real-time and highly-accurate detection of travel mode
(an overall accuracy of 96% in classifying motorized vs. non-motorized trip
segments and an overall accuracy of 86% in classifying travel modes across six
mode options including car, bus, rail, wait, bike, and walk) and trip purposes
(an accuracy larger than 95% in detecting trip purposes when trips taking place
at previously identified location); second, on-the-fly visualization and
annotation; and third, continuous self-improvement of its detection modules
(Fan et al., 2015). 5.3 Quantified
Self and the Potential of Travel Behavior Intervention
Research has shown that generic mass media intervention can
be used in raising the awareness of the health benefits associated with
sustainable transportation (e.g., the U.S. Walk to School programs) and in
increasing walking and biking mode share (Ward et al., 2007). However, critics
question the effectiveness of generic information in bringing about sustained
behavioral change. It is suggested that interventions that are closely tailored
to individual needs may include less redundant information and are more likely
to be read, saved, remembered, and discussed (Smeets et al., 2008). With
increasingly quantified travel behavior, many of the travel quantification apps
can be designed as smartphone-based behavior intervention tool for promoting
travel mode shifts from driving to more sustainable modes. For example, building upon existing apps’
data collection capabilities, intervention-driven tools can be designed to
provide customized messages and action plans to the user after detection of
each driving trip. The tool can incorporate a combination of three strategies
to promote mode shifts:
Awareness:
Messages describing environmental impacts associated with each driving trip
(e.g., carbon emissions) could be displayed to the user.
Motivation:
Messages describing personal benefits of a mode shift (e.g., cost savings and
health benefits) could be displayed to the user to reinforce positive aspects
of transit and nonmotorized travel.
Action: Implementable mode-shift
plans could be provided to the user through the phone. For example, if the
application detects a driving trip made from home to a grocery store, the tool
could utilize maps of bike rental facilities and public transit services to
provide information on how to travel to the destination by alternative
transportation modes, including information on where and how to rent a bike or
board a bus/train as well as information on the best walking/biking/transit
routes.
There is no shortage of
health-oriented apps (e.g., Moves and Apple HealthKit) that could promote
travel-related physical activity, such as walking and biking. Yet,
neither set of apps can effectively and systematically promote travel mode
shifts from driving to more sustainable modes—they were simply not designed for
that purpose. Nonetheless, the success of health-oriented apps provides
important insights into the potential of travel quantification apps in behavior
intervention. Several previous studies have evaluated the use of mobile phones
to support healthcare and public health interventions (Kailas et al., 2010;
Boulos et al., 2011; Dennison et al., 2013). There is consensus that
smartphones have the following advantages for delivering of health-promoting
behavioral interventions (Dennison et al., 2013):
Portable
devices offer the opportunity to bring behavioral interventions into important
real life contexts where people make decisions about their health and encounter
barriers to behavior change.
Smartphone
apps may provide cheaper, more convenient, or less stigmatizing interventions
that are unavailable elsewhere.
The
connectedness of smartphones facilitates the sharing of behavioral and health
data with health professionals or peers.
Smartphones
enables continuous and automated tracking of health-related behaviors and
timely, tailored interventions for specific contexts.
These same advantages could
apply to smartphone apps that aims to promote travel sustainability. The 2015
Urban Mobility Scorecard shows that urban areas of all sizes are experiencing
increased congestions (Schrank et al., 2015). The Twin Cities region has worse
congestion than ever before. As of 2014, the region’s congestion problem
resulted in 99.7 million person-hours of annual travel delay and 38.5 million
gallons of annual excess fuel consumption. The smartphone-based quantified-self
technologies offer opportunities to develop efficient, low-cost, and innovative
approaches to collecting detailed travel behavior data as well as promoting
sustainable travel behavior.
5.4 Discussion on Quantified Self and Quantified Networks
Compared to mobility-related Quantified Self
technologies, roadway-based vehicle detection and surveillance technologies are
relatively mature technologies that have been used to support traffic
management and traveler information services. The roadway based sensors have
been used across transportation networks to provide enhanced speed monitoring,
traffic counting, presence detection, headway measurement, vehicle
classification, and weigh-in-motion data (i.e., to provide quantified network
data). Mimbela and Klein (2007) categorized roadway-based sensors into two
major groups:
In-roadway sensors: Sensors are either
embedded in the pavement/subgrade of a roadway or tapped/attached to the
surface of the roadway. Examples include inductive loop detectors,
weigh-in-motion sensors, magnetometers, pneumatic road tubes, etc.
Over-roadway
sensors: Sensors are mounted above the surface of the roadway either above the
roadway itself or alongside the roadway (offset from the nearest traffic lane
by some distance). Examples include video image processors, microwave radar
sensors, ultrasonic sensors, acoustic sensors, iBeacons/Bluetooth transmitters,
etc.
To date, roadway-based sensor
technologies have only limited interactions with smartphone-based sensor
technologies. Yet, the potential for the two types of technologies to interact
is strong:
Roadway sensors can provide time-dynamic
data on transportation networks that can help to improve data processing
modules to derive more accurate travel behavior information from smartphone
sensor data. For example, when it comes to identifying activities vs. trips
using smartphone sensor data, existing technology heavily depends on speed. As
a result, trips in congested roadways or encountering an accident are likely to
be identified as activities. Roadway sensors that can monitor traffic accidents
and traffic congestion could be used to improve trip identification. In addition, new sensors that employ
iBeacons/Bluetooth technology can provide more accurate location and proximity
data than smartphone built-in location sensors. Such highly accurate location
identification technology can help disadvantaged people such as the visually
impaired to navigate transportation systems.
Smartphone sensors can capture
dimension of data that current roadway sensors have difficulties in capturing
such as acceleration patterns. Combining smartphone sensor data and roadway
sensor data will allow transportation agencies to better understand traffic
patterns and generate better data to support traffic management.
The following issues merit
discussion when it comes to possible integrations between quantified self and
quantified networks technologies:
Smartphone sensors are sensitive to
environmental conditions such as heavy rain/snow, urban canyon, extreme hot or
cold temperature, etc. Although in-roadway sensors have relatively consistent
performance across environmental conditions, many of the overroadway sensors
are sensitive to various environmental conditions. How the smartphone sensors
and roadway sensors can be integrated to provide robust data across extreme
environmental conditions merits future research.
Most
of the roadway sensors focus on detecting motor vehicles. Although there has
been substantial progress made in roadway sensing technologies for detecting
pedestrian and bicycle traffic, such technologies are much less mature.
Smartphone technologies are especially good at detecting non-motorized modes,
yet relatively weak to distinguish between private car and public transit
especially in urban traffic without using public transit infrastructure data.
How the two sets of technologies be integrated to generate multi-modal data
merits future research.
One
fundamental concern about smartphone apps for mobility data capture is the
battery power consumption. Since the battery power depletes rapidly from
frequent and continuous operation of multiple sensors, especially the GPS
receiver, the inconvenience caused by frequent battery recharge often drives
away users and offsets the potential benefits of using those apps. When
properly integrated, roadway sensing technologies (e.g., transiting location/speed
data to smartphones so that smartphones need not to use GPS receiver to capture
location/speed data) may offer opportunities for smartphone apps to preserve
battery power.
The
usage of some roadway sensors (especially in-roadway sensors) tend to be
expensive as their installation and maintenance often require pavement cut
and/or lane closure. With sufficient user base, smartphone data may have the
potential to eliminate the needs for more expensive roadway sensors. Companies
such as AirSage have explored ways to aggregate signaling data from cellular
networks to provide real-time speed and travel times for major roads. How
smartphone data may replace/substitute part of the roadway sensor data merits
future research.
Privacy
will be a major concern for possible integration between Quantified Self and
Quantified Networks technology since few people would want to be tracked in
their daily life even in cases when the collected data is used for research.
Who will own the data? Who can use the data? What type of smartphone and
roadway data can be integrated for future analysis? Data security and privacy protection issues
are critical issues meriting future research.
Chapter 6: Electrification and Alternative Fuels
6.1 Introduction
The current mix of fuels to power on-road
vehicles is diversifying at an increasing rate. Desires to reduce greenhouse
gas emissions, noxious emissions, fuel use, foreign oil consumption and cost of
driving have led to a new era of power use for transportation. While gasoline
remains the dominant fuel for light duty vehicles and diesel the dominant fuel
for heavy duty vehicles in Minnesota and the US, an increasing percentage of
vehicle power is being derived from “alternative” transportation fuels, such as
biofuels, natural gas and electricity. The largest use of alternative fuels in
the State of Minnesota is a result of legislative mandates that require fuel
retailers to blend quantities of biofuels with traditional fossil-derived
transportation fuels. The “drop-in” replacement fuels do not require a
specialized fleet of vehicles to use these fuels and thus do not drastically
affect the type of vehicles on the roadways. Other alternative fuels, such as
electricity or natural gas, require specialized powertrains that differ from
conventional gasoline and diesel-powered vehicles. This report refers to both
drop-in replacement fuels and fuels requiring specific drive trains as
alternative fuels.
Issues with alternative fuel use
that are relevant for the Minnesota Department of
Transportation include,
1. Loss
of tax revenue for roads as result of switching to fuels that do not have
highway tax
2. Change
of vehicle mass as a result of alternative vehicle power train
3. Change
in vehicle emissions and resulting air quality (mobile emissions sources vs.
point sources)
4. Change
in vehicle activity and ownership costs
5. Refueling
and charging infrastructure
6. Travel
times and robustness
7. Increased
difference in weight between heavy duty and light duty vehicles as a result of
power train and emphasis on fuel efficiency
Important drivers of the impacts of
alternative fuel use are the degree to which alternative fuels are being
adopted in on-road vehicles in the Minnesota transportation fleet, whereby the
majority of fuel shifting has resulted from increased use of ethanol in light
duty vehicles (displacing gasoline), increased use of biodiesel in heavy goods
vehicles (displacing diesel), increased use of electricity as a primary power
source, and increased use of natural gas (compressed and liquefied) as a
fuel.
This report discusses the current and likely future trends
of alternative fuel use in the State of
Minnesota and the subsequent impact of alternative fuel use
on issues relevant to the Minnesota Department of Transportation for each of
the major alternative fuels being adopted within Minnesota.
6.2 Alternative Fuel Vehicle Trends
The adoption of alternative fuels differs
greatly by the type and availability of alternative fuel. The following
sections discuss trends of the major fuels that are achieving penetration in
the Minnesota vehicle fleet.
6.3 Drop-in Biofuels
Drop-in replacement biofuels,
such as ethanol and biodiesel have grown rapidly since their first adoption in
the early 1990s. The national consumption of ethanol and biodiesel has
undergone near exponential growth since the year 2000 as a result of a mix of
mandated blend levels from states and federal government, as well as
incentives.
The stated aims by the Minnesota
Department of Agriculture for ethanol and biodiesel production and use within
the State of Minnesota are to provide a new market for agricultural products,
displace fossil fuels and help meet the US EPA standards for carbon monoxide
within the Minneapolis-St. Paul metropolitan area. To achieve these aims, the
State of Minnesota has adopted a series of legislative acts to encourage
ethanol production and consumption beginning in 1980 with legislation that
offered a 4 cent per gallon pump tax credit for 10% ethanol blends. By 1986, forty
percent of the state’s gasoline was blended with 10% ethanol as concerns over
other oxygenates (MTBE) increased. Further legislation reduced the pump tax
credit to 2 cents and initiated a 20 cent per gallon incentive payment for
ethanol produced in the state. In 1992, a minimum 2.7% oxygen content
requirement was established for gasoline. It was made effective for the entire
year (as opposed to just summer months when air quality is worse) in the
Minneapolis St. Paul metropolitan area in 1995 and then statewide in 1997.
In 1994, the pump tax credit was phased
out while oxygen requirements for fuel statewide were phased in. In 1995, a
statutory goal to develop 220 million gallons of Minnesota ethanol production
was established, which was further expanded to 240 million gallons in 1998. By
2000 all other oxygenates (MTBE) were effectively eliminated, leaving ethanol
as the only oxygenate allowed in attempt to reduce groundwater contamination
while controlling unburned hydrocarbon and carbon monoxide production. Producer
payments were reduced to 13 cents per gallon for fiscal years 2004 through
2007. The ethanol production goal was to increase to 480 million gallons by
2008 and the 2.7% oxygenate requirement (equivalent to a 7.4% volume of
ethanol) for gasoline was replaced by 10% ethanol requirement (3.65 %
oxygenate).
In 2005, law required a 20% ethanol
content or a maximum of what the EPA allowed (known as the blend wall) in all
gasoline by 2013, which had been delayed to start by August 30, 2015 were the
EPA to have approved higher blend levels (E15 or E20). The EPA did extend the
blend level to E15 for 2001 and newer vehicles, but Minnesota has not mandated
E15 statewide due to the restriction on older vehicles. There are currently 36
E15 retail locations in Minnesota in addition to the 263 station that sell E30
or E85 that are available exclusively for flex-fuel vehicles[47].
The pressure to increase the fraction of ethanol within gasoline has diminished
as the US has increased domestic oil production, lessening the demand for
foreign oil [1]. An ongoing debate continues as to whether ethanol blend levels
should be raised, as concerns over the energy and environmental implications of
corn-based ethanol production are being investigated [2-4].
As a result of these incentives
nearly 20% of Minnesota’s corn crop is converted to ethanol in Minnesota’s 21
refineries with a nameplate production capacity of over 1 billion gallons (76
trillion BTUs) of ethanol each year, which allows 10% of Minnesota gasoline to
be replaced by ethanol. The shipments of agricultural commodities throughout
the state are affected by these programs, and resulting road use in rural areas
differs as more agricultural products are trucked short distances from nearby
farms to local refineries, rather than placed on rail and shipped out of state
to foreign markets.
Similar legislation has affected the
quantity of biodiesel produced and consumed within the State of Minnesota. In
2005 Minnesota law required that a minimum of 2% biodiesel be blended in all
diesel fuel sold in the state for on-road purposes (thus excluding locomotives
and mining equipment). In 2009 the required percentage of biodiesel in
Minnesota increased to 5% and in 2014 increased again to 10% biodiesel.
Currently the 10% biodiesel mandate is achieved by a 15% biodiesel blend level
in summer months (April through September) and then a 5% blend level in winter
months. Beginning in 2018 the summer blend level will increase to 20% and the
winter level will remain at 5%. As a result of the mandates, the State of
Minnesota produces nearly all of its biodiesel within the state, which accounts
for nearly 13% of the state soybean crop. [5]
Minnesota leads the nation in terms
of biofuel use, but national policy has also increased domestic biofuel use.
The primary drivers for biofuel use at the national level have been legislation
enacted that requires the amount of biofuels produced and blended to achieve
specific targets by given dates. The Renewable Fuel Standard (RFS) was first
enacted in 2005 and required that 7.5 billion gallons of renewable fuels
(primarily achieved with corn ethanol) be blended into gasoline by 2012. The
Energy Independence and Security Act (EISA) of 2007 expanded the RFS program,
now called RFS2, to blend higher levels of fuel increasing from 9 billion
gallons in 2008 to 36 billion gallons by 2022 [6]. The EISA also distinguished
renewable fuels by their lifecycle greenhouse gas (GHG) impact, as a primary
driver for the increased production of renewable fuels was to lower the GHG
emissions associated with fuel use. RFS2 required that both renewable diesel
and gasoline alternatives achieve specific GHG reductions relative to the
displaced fuel. Since the adoption of the standard, the EPA has made multiple
modifications to the program as production of ethanol from non-corn sources,
called advanced biofuels and cellulosic biofuels, have not been achieved thus
forcing the EPA to reduce the required amount of advanced and cellulosic biofuel
use.
Historically,
domestic ethanol production has been protected by tariffs on foreign ethanol
imports. A 54 cent per gallon import tariff effectively prohibited importation
of Brazilian sugarcane ethanol, which is more efficient to refine than corn.
The foreign tariff and 45 cent per gallon tax credit to blenders were
eliminated in 2012 allowing open access to the US market for foreign biofuel
producers.
Figure 6.1 shows the quantity of
ethanol and biodiesel consumed within the US from 1980 to
2014. Over the same period total fossil fuel consumption
increased from 19,000 to 24,826 Trillion BTUs [7], resulting in a total biofuel
consumption of 5.6% for transportation activities in 2014. As seen the
consumption of biofuels increased dramatically in 2000 as a result of
legislation nationally and in individual states to encourage biofuel
production. The levels of ethanol consumption have plateaued since 2010 as a
result of an inability to meet RFS2 targets with low GHG ethanol, and increased
concerns over the environmental performance of corn-based ethanol. Biodiesel consumption has continued to
increase since 2010 due to greater demand and less concern of environmental
performance. The lifecycle GHG emissions associated from biodiesel are less than
half (≈76% reduction) of those associated with diesel fuel use even when
accounting for land use changes [8]. As a result the total biodiesel fuel
content continues to increase but will likely plateau in the future due to cold
weather blending limitations and lower yields of biodiesel per acre when
compared to corn or cellulosic ethanol, see Table 6.1.
Table 6.1: Ethanol and biodiesel yield per
acre from selected crops. [9]
Standard 2nd Implementation [10]
and revised by the EPA in 2014 [11].
National levels of biofuel
consumption are likely to plateau near the current levels of consumption, as
shown in Figure 6.2. The Energy Information Administration historic [7] and
projected [12] levels of biofuel consumption within the transportation and
liquid fuels sector indicate that the US is near the peak of biofuel
consumption at 6.3% of total fuel use. The production of biofuels is projected
to increase, but will remain stable relative to the consumption of total fuel
use, e.g. both total fuel use and biofuel production will increase
proportionally. Dynamics are likely to occur within the mix of biofuels
produced and consumed. As technology develops and RFS2 mandates incentivize
greater production of fuels from non-food sources, such as cellulose and crop
residues, there may be larger sources of advanced and cellulosic fuels
available. Long term pressures for reduced greenhouse gas emissions and
sustainable agricultural practices may present a competition in supply of
biomass products, as the electrical sector seeks to decarbonize coal-fired
electric power production with increasing fraction of biomass co-firing. The
relative levels of biomass that are dedicated to electricity versus liquid transportation
fuel production are likely to be a result of government incentives, suitable
low carbon substitutes and the evolution of the transportation fleet from
liquid-fueled vehicles to vehicles powered by electricity and other energy
carriers.
Figure 6.2: Historic
and projected biofuel consumption of total fuel use where blue dots represent
historic data [7] and black dots represent projections by the Energy
Information
Administration [12] and the black line
represents predicted percentage of biofuel use as predicted by S-Curve (S(t) =
K/[1+exp(-b(t-t0)], K=0.063, b=0.38, t0=2008, R2=0.9904)
6.4 Electric Vehicles
Vehicles powered by electricity offer an
alternative to liquid fueled vehicles and have received increased attention
over the last decade. The primary drivers of electric vehicle technology are
the desire to reduce noxious emissions in urban areas and greenhouse gas
emissions globally. As shown in Figure 6.3, the sales of electric drives has
increased steadily since 2000 with hybridized electric vehicles (HEVs) reaching
roughly 6% of the new car vehicle sales market. While HEVs derive all of their
power from liquid fuels, fully electric vehicles (EVs) and plug-in hybrid
electric vehicles (PHEVs) are able to derive at least a portion of their
electricity from the power grid, thus displacing liquid transportation fuel
use. PHEVs and EVs are relatively newer technologies within the market and are
still undergoing development by many manufacturers with most offerings on the
market representing the initial model available from the manufacturer. The
split in sales between EVs and PHEVs is roughly equal with 152,000 EVs and
164,000 PHEVs sold in the US market from 2011 to April 2015 [13]. Globally the
number of vehicles with electric drives within the fleet (excluding non-plug in
hybrids) has been doubling every year for the past three years, and could reach
1 million vehicles globally if trends continue by 2016[48].
Figure 6.3: Total US new car sales from
1990 to 2015 [14], as well as percentage of hybrid electric vehicles (HEV) and
combined electric vehicle and plug-in hybrid electric vehicle sales [13].
In Minnesota
the trends for HEV, EV and PHEV sales have lagged those of the national
economy, as the share of Minnesota vehicle sales with hybrid drives has
plateaued at 2 to 3.5% since 2009, as shown in Figure 6.4. The adoption of
electric vehicle drives has been delayed as a result of higher prices for
vehicles, cold winter-time temperatures which lowers electric vehicle range and
a lack of state incentives that encourage purchase of electric drive vehicles.
Also, corporate average fuel economy (CAFE) standards have increased the fuel
efficiency of non-hybrid vehicles lowering the gains of hybrid drives relative
to traditional vehicles. The low fuel prices of 2014 and 2015 are likely to
keep the sales of hybrid drive vehicles low. Long-term increases in sales of
electric drive vehicles are likely to be driven by national incentives and
regulation seeking to reduce GHG emissions.
Figure 6.4: New car sales and percentage of
vehicles with electric drives (HEVs, PHEVs and EVs) in Minnesota from 2008 to
2014 [15].
6.4.1 Powering Electric Vehicles
The primary inhibitor to electric vehicle
penetration is the size and cost of the battery required to achieve a range
that is acceptable to consumers. The industry remains divided on how to provide
a vehicle with the typical 200 to 300 mile range that is expected by consumers,
with nearly half of the manufacturers providing PHEVs which have a small
battery capacity able to deliver a portion of the drive in all electric mode
(typically, 20-50 miles) and others providing full EVs with larger battery
packs able to deliver a total range of greater than 100 miles. As the electrical
storage capacity of vehicles increases, the weight and cost of the vehicle rise
proportionally. However, by converting to full EV rather than PHEV, the
manufacturer is able to eliminate duplicate engine and motor systems lowering
manufacturing costs.
The optimal size of full electric
capacity was studied for PHEVs and EVs and it was found that for the average US
commuting distance a PHEV with an all-electric range of 20 miles optimizes
vehicle cost, gasoline consumption and greenhouse gas emissions [16]. As prices
fall and the weight of batteries decrease (energy densities rise), increased
electrical capacity is optimal and more cost effective. A study of consumers’
willingness to pay for EV attributes found that consumers require pay back
periods of 5 years to offset the initial EV cost premium. Battery prices of
$300-350 per kWh are required to achieve a 5 year payback with the current
$7,500 federal tax credit [17]. While $300 per kWh battery costs are below the
current industry average, a recent study found that the that EV battery costs
are declining by 14% annually, from above $1,000 per kWh nearly a decade ago to
around $410 per kWh in 2014, and that the cost of battery packs used by
market-leading EV manufacturers are even lower, at $300 per kWh [18].
As PHEVs and EVs become more prevalent,
the number of charging stations must increase to allow for reliable charging
throughout the transportation network. Currently 10,409 public charging
stations are available within the US (in comparison there are 121,000 gas
stations) of which 192 are located in Minnesota [19]. For full coverage the
State of Minnesota would need to have charging stations roughly every 100
miles, along with at-home charging. While the
Minneapolis-St. Paul metropolitan area has a high density of
stations, outstate areas require higher density to allow full access to all
state locations with EVs.
6.4.2 Electric Vehicle Penetration
The electric vehicle penetration
rates for the light duty vehicle fleet were estimated by fitting Scurves to the
adoption rate of HEVs and combined PHEV and EVs in the US fleet. The historic
HEV trends provided sufficient data to fit an S-curve to and it was assumed
that EV and PHEV adoption would follow a similar adoption rate delay by 10
years. As shown in Figure 6.5, the adoption of HEVs in the US fleet is expected
to grow until it reached 30% market share by 2035 and then decrease thereafter
as PHEV and EVs begin to eclipse HEV sales in 2037. The growth of PHEV and EV
sales nationally are expected to increase from their current levels in 2014 to
achieve a 24% new car sales penetration in 2035 and 68% penetration in 2050.
The penetration of PHEV and EV sales in the State of Minnesota is expected to
lag the penetration rate of sales nationally by four years, as is the case for
current HEV adoption in Minnesota relative to the US. Therefore, the
penetration of PHEV and EVs for new cars sold in Minnesota is 16% in 2035 and
56% in 2050. The modeled rate of growth corresponds to a near 20% annual increase
in PHEV and EV sales until 2030 before leveling off, which agrees with
projections of EV sales by the International Energy Agency. [24]
The penetration
of HEV, PHEV and EVs into the stock of all vehicles within the State of
Minnesota will lag the penetration of electric drive vehicles into new car
sales. The average age of light duty vehicle in the US is 11.5 years old [25]
and thus the time required for the total vehicle stock to reach the levels
shown in Figure 6.5 will lag the makeup of new car sales by more than 10 years.
The adoption of
electric drive technology within the heavy duty vehicle fleet will be
significantly more limited. Specialized routes that require stop and start
vehicle operation, such as those traveled by buses and garbage trucks, are
likely to adopt a degree of electric hybridization. A recent study of bus
fleets has shown that hybrid-electric bus operation can reduce fuel consumption
and help to achieve noxious and GHG emissions reductions within urban
environments, but costs for hybrid conversion must be reduced for the emissions
savings to be cost effective relative to traditional diesel technologies.
[26]
Figure 6.5: Historic
[13] and projected HEV (blue circles) and combined PHEV and EV (red circles)
adoption rate as a percentage of total new car sales for the US and MN. The
dotted,
solid and dashed black lines represent the predicted percentage of US HEVs, US PHEV and
EVs, and Minnesota PHEV and EV as
determined by S-Curve fits (S(t) = K/[1+exp(-b(t-t0)], K=0.95, b=0.13, t0,US=2043,
t0,MN=2043, R2=0.79).
6.4.3 Dynamic Wireless Power Transfer
Due to the
limitations of vehicle batteries (weight and charging), recent efforts have
sought to identify the potential for on-road charging via dynamic wireless
power transfer (DWPT). DWPT approaches embed charging coils within the roadways
to transfer power to vehicles while in use. The UK government recently released
the most comprehensive feasibility study to date on DWPT, which included a
large survey of stakeholders, identified technology requirements, examined
costs and impacts and outlined future on-road testing of the system. [20]
Respondents to the surveys indicated
that industrial stakeholders and private consumers are more likely to purchase an
EV if DWPT was available on highways. Private consumers also expressed an
interest in deployment of DWPT capacity on A roads (major highways). The
adoption of vehicles with DWPT charging capability is likely to require an 18
month to three year return on investment and would require that the DWPT system
be user-friendly, practical and simple and reduce CO2 emissions.
[20]
DWTP vehicles are likely to be more
expensive than EVs, which are already more expensive than diesel and gasoline
vehicles. Early adopters of the DWTP technology are likely to include light
weight delivery vehicles (< 32 tons). [20]
The DWPT technologies evaluated
(17 total) were found to be between a Technology
Readiness Level (TRL) 4 and 8
with a manufacturing readiness level (MRL) between 3 and 7. No DWPT systems are
currently available on the open market, although several are undergoing
experimental trials. It was suggested that DWPT technologies could support
autonomous vehicle functionality which would add to the benefits of installation.
Installation of the DWTP system could coincide with load sensors and other
maintenance. [20]
EV batteries and required DWTP
charging systems depend on the vehicle and drive cycle with larger, heavier vehicles
requiring substantially higher power transfer. Cars, vans and SUVs could viably
be used in fully electric mode, with, DWPT increasing range and/or reducing
required battery capacity. Heavy duty trucks, however, have a larger power
requirement than what would be practical for DWTP to provide thus limiting
heavy duty trucks to operation in hybrid mode. [20]
Three different DWTP installation
practices are considered: trench-based construction (where a trench is
excavated in the roadway for installation of the DWPT primary coils), full lane
reconstruction (where the full depth of bound layers are removed, the primary
coils installed and the whole lane resurfaced), and full lane prefabricated
construction (where the full depth of bound layers are removed and replaced by
pre-fabricated full lane width sections containing the complete in-road
system). The trench-based and full lane reconstruction were identified as
cost-effective options, whereas full lane prefabrication was too new to confirm
as a cost-effective option.[20]
Off road trials were suggested
with different DWPT road construction methods and different
DWPT system manufacturers to investigate the potential long
term impacts on road degradation. Test track trials are planned that investigate
the system charging performance, reliability and safety that will be conducted.
[20]
South Korea is
currently trialing DWPT charging along a 15 mile stretch of road in an 8 km (5
mile) stretch of highway in the Gumi. So far during testing, engineers have
recorded an 85% transmission efficiency with the cables and coils. [21]
An alternative to charging batteries
is combining fast charging systems with super (or ultra) capacitor energy
storage. Supercapacitors have a high power density that allows them to charge
and discharge faster than typical batteries. The high power density of
capacitors is offset by the energy density which is an order of magnitude or
more lower than conventional batteries, see Figure 6.6. The higher power
density lends itself well to intermittent charging systems whereby regularly
spaced charging on specific routes can satisfy driving demands even for large
public transit system. Demonstrator projects are being trailed in the China for
above-ground streetcars that are able to be installed without overhead wires
and have lower capital and operating costs than continuous coils [22]. The
multiple charging and storage technologies highlight the opportunities for
optimization of vehicle storage and charging systems. In the Minnesota context, Arterial BRT would
be an opportunity to consider for DWPT.
Figure 6.6: Energy and power density of
energy storage technologies that can be supplied to vehicles. [23]
6.5 Natural Gas
While the light duty vehicle fleet is
likely to increase the adoption of electric drivetrains, the power requirements
for heavy duty vehicles are prohibitive for current and foreseen battery
technology. Therefore, fleet managers are seeking other power sources to enable
lower operational cost, reduced noxious and lower GHG emissions. An emerging
fuel alternative is natural gas which has become attractive in recent years as
a result of the low price of natural gas relative to diesel fuel.
Natural gas
offers several advantages to diesel fuel. It has lower CO2 emissions
per unit energy (50.3 gCO2/MJ) than diesel fuel (69.4 gCO2/MJ),
produces less particulate matter and NOx emissions than diesel
fuels, and has been 20-40% cheaper than diesel fuel on an equivalent energy
basis since 2005 [27]. Conversely, natural gas has a lower energy density per
unit volume (9.3 MJ/L) than diesel (35.8 MJ/L), typically has lower combustion
efficiency, and when used in internal combustion engines can emit significant
quantities of methane resulting in higher GHG emissions than diesel engines.
[26]
Despite the disadvantages, the benefits
of natural gas as a transportation fuel have resulted in an increased adoption
rate of the energy source for heavy duty vehicles. As shown in Figure 6.7, the
EIA predicts that natural gas will be consumed at increasing rates for heavy
duty vehicle use. By 2040 the percentage of natural gas use is expected to
reach nearly 7% of total energy use for the heavy duty vehicle sector.
Figure 6.7: Natural gas portion of heavy
duty fuel use projection from 2012 to 2040 [28].
In order to enable natural gas heavy duty
vehicles a sufficient refueling infrastructure must be in place to provide full
deployment. Cities such as Los Angeles have recently deployed compressed
natural gas (CNG) refueling stations throughout the metropolitan area, which
has allowed them to adopt a bus fleet almost entirely powered by natural gas
[29]. The benefit of using natural gas fuel outweighs the additional cost of
CNG vehicles (≈10%) when the price of natural gas is 40–50% below diesel
prices. This price differential maintains the payback period at 3–4 years or
less [30].
6.6 Other Fuel Alternatives
Many other fuels have been offered as an
alternative to traditional gasoline and diesel fuels. Additional liquid
hydrocarbons, such as dimethyl ether, methanol and butanol, may be combusted in
internal combustion engines similar to gasoline and diesel
6.7 Fuel Tax Revenue
Fuel tax
revenues are likely to decrease from duties imposed on gasoline and diesel fuel
use in the future. The primary driver for decreased revenues in the short and
medium term is the increase in vehicle fuel efficiencies resulting from CAFE
regulations. The Congressional Budget Office estimates that fuel tax revenues
could fall by as much as 21% by 2040 relative to 2012 levels. [31]
Alternative fuels are taxed at the
pump in a similar manner to gasoline and diesel, however different tax rates
apply in Minnesota. The Minnesota Department of Revenue taxes E85 at the pump
at a rate of $0.2025 per gallon, pure biodiesel (B100) is taxed at $0.285,
liquefied natural gas is taxed at $0.171 per gallon, and compressed natural gas
is taxed at the rate of $2.474 per thousand cubic feet. Gasoline and diesel are
both taxed at the rate of $0.285 per gallon. [32] Currently, the State of
Minnesota does not tax electricity for vehicles, while five other states (CO,
NE, NC, VA and WA) all have enacted some form of tax on electricity used for
transportation. As electric vehicles begin to makeup a larger portion of the
fleet taxes on electricity used to power vehicles will likely be adopted within
all states including Minnesota (See
Chapter 7). Ironically, given Minnesota’s Motor Vehicle Sales Tax, current
price differentials between electric and conventional vehicles lead to greater
sales tax revenue that currently offset the fuel tax revenue losses from
electric vehicle charging. The differential may decrease as battery and
electric vehicle prices come down.
6.8 Vehicle Mass
Alternative fuels offer the
opportunity to alter the drivetrain and thus impact vehicle characteristics
such as acceleration and mass. Vehicle mass in turn impacts both the road
network and fuel consumption of the transportation fleet. A focus on increasing
fuel efficiency of the vehicle fleet will have the opposite effect on light
duty and heavy duty vehicles, as the relationship between fuel consumption and
mass encourages mass reduction in light duty vehicles and increased delivery
weight of heavy goods vehicles.
Recent work by Martin [33] has
demonstrated that the mass of vehicles has remained relatively constant in
recent years, but gains in fuel efficiency are possible as a result of vehicle
mass reduction. For light duty vehicles a Ricardo analysis found a 0.5-1.5%
improvement in fuel economy was shown possible for every 100 lb. (45 kg)
decrease in vehicle weight for a range of vehicle classes and engines [34]. An
analysis by Heywood et al. has predicted that it is possible for the light duty
fleet to reduce vehicle mass by 20% for like vehicles [34]. While the reduction
in vehicle weight is achievable within individual vehicles or vehicle segments,
the total weight of the vehicle fleet is ultimately determined by consumer
choice amongst vehicle segments, where trends have shown an increase in the
purchase of larger vehicle classes. The available US light duty vehicle market
has seen an increase in SUVs since their introduction in the 1980s, now
representing 37% of all vehicles sold in 2015, which tend to be larger and
heavier [35]. Consumer vehicle choice is influenced by a mix of vehicle
attributes of which mass is influenced by preferences for increased
acceleration and fuel efficiency. As shown in Figure 6.8, the mass of vehicles
has remained nearly constant for the last decade while fuel economy has
improved and acceleration has increased as a result of engine
improvements.
Significant reductions in vehicle mass
would be possible as a result of more dramatic shifts in the vehicle ownership
model. Vehicle sharing programs such as Car2Go increase the possibility of
deploying large number of small vehicles within the transportation network that
are specifically suited to transporting individuals, and thus, negate the need
for larger vehicles that are often purchased in order to serve a variety of
vehicle tasks (See Chapter 4). The
changes in the ownership model are likely to coincide with other shifts in the
light duty vehicle sector, such as adoption of autonomous vehicles (Chapter 1) and vehicle electrification. People may also be more willing to use light
and narrow one-person autonomous vehicles that were considered safe and
enclosed from the elements (unlike today’s motorcycles).
Figure 6.8: Change in adjusted fuel
economy, weight and horsepower from model year 1975 to 2014. [35]
Within the heavy duty vehicle fleet, the
drive for fuel efficiency encourages fleet owners to carry larger loads which
reduce the fuel consumption per ton-mile of delivered good. Heavy duty vehicles
have significantly higher fuel consumption per ton-mile (or per tonne-km) when
operated with partial loads. As shown in Figure 6.9, the energy index
(kJ/tonne-km) is highest for small trucks with low load factors (the load
factor is the fraction of load the vehicle is carrying relative to its full
mass load capacity). There is a ≈45% energy index penalty for half loaded
vehicles. The energy index reduces as the delivery vehicle size increases from
Rigid to A-Double.
An analysis of worldwide truck
fleets indicates that Australia's truck freight transport is the least energy
intensive, using about a quarter less energy per ton-mile than truck freight
transport in the United States. This is in part a consequence of a high share
of three-unit long haul trucks responsible for transporting a majority of
freight through Australia’s interior. [36]
Figure 6.9: Energy index of heavy duty
trucks for varying load factors. (Courtesy Prof. David Cebon, University of
Cambridge).
6.9 Conclusion and Discussion
As alternative fuels are adopted within
Minnesota there are likely to be a number of impacts to the state’s
transportation sector. It is likely that biofuel consumption is near saturation
and future shifts will likely be between biofuels, as efforts focus on advanced
and cellulosic biofuel production and consumption. These shifts may alter the
routes of heavy goods vehicles in the state, as refineries shift from corn and
soy feed stocks to cellulose derived from agricultural wastes and forest
byproducts. In all cases the increased demand on Minnesota roadways is likely
to be minimal as refineries will seek to locate their facilities as close as
possible to biomass sources to lower production costs.
Electrification
of the vehicle fleet is likely to occur within the light duty vehicle sector.
The increased number of electric vehicles will require increased deployment of
charging infrastructure. In order to encourage adoption of electric power
trains charging stations must likely be supplied or subsidized by government
agencies to develop a sufficient network of stations. Long term potential
exists for deployment of an on-road charging system which would drastically
improve vehicle efficiencies by reducing the weight of batteries required to be
carried within vehicles. The installation and maintenance costs for on-road
charging are not well known and are an area of ongoing study.
Natural gas vehicles are likely to become
an increasing share of heavy duty vehicle fleet so long as the price of natural
gas remains 40-50% lower than diesel fuel on an equivalent energy basis. A
larger natural gas refueling infrastructure will need to be developed in order
to serve an increased number of natural gas vehicles. It is likely that the
refueling infrastructure will be developed by private organizations that manage
fleets of vehicles with distinct end points. Larger deployment of natural gas
vehicles would be enabled by state incentives for natural gas refueling
infrastructure. Efforts must ensure that natural gas vehicles and refueling
infrastructure do not emit significant quantities of methane, as the high
global warming potential (34 times greater than CO2) can negate any
GHG benefits relative to diesel fuel.
Fuel tax
revenues are likely to decline in future years as a result of improved vehicle
efficiency, rather than a switch to different fuels. Despite the drive for fuel
efficiency and incentivize electric vehicle use, a method for producing
revenues from electrically-powered vehicles will need to implemented by the
State of Minnesota to maintain a long-term funding mechanism for the
transportation road network.
Finally emphasis on fuel efficiency in
the light duty and heavy duty vehicle fleet is likely going to drive the weight
of the vehicle segments in opposite directions. Light duty vehicles are likely
to get lighter, especially as different ownership models allow for dedicated
light duty vehicle fleets that focus on fuel efficiency for personal mobility.
Heavy-duty vehicle fleet operators are likely to lobby for increased vehicle
weight limits on Minnesota roadways in order to reduce the energy intensity of
goods deliveries. The growing disparity in weight between the two vehicle
classes may necessitate increased safety measures to reduce the severity of crashes
between the disparate vehicle classes.
Chapter 7: Road Pricing
7.1 Introduction
Today, nationally user fees are not the primary
source of roadway funds. This is especially true for local roads, as most
localities fail to have a user fee the way states do, and instead rely
primarily on property taxes (with some transfer of funds from the state, which
may or may not be user-fee based). General revenue sources spread costs across
non-users as well as users. They also send no signal about the appropriate
amount of roads that should be built or how scarce road space should be
allocated. Like everything this share is
disputed and depends on accounting (For instance, are Motor Vehicle Sales Taxes
a user fee? Not if there is a general sales tax and motor vehicles are exempted
from it, yes if they are in addition to it. Are gasoline taxes a user fee? Yes,
except if gasoline is exempted from standard sales taxes that applies to most
goods, in which case there is a hidden cross-subsidy. These vary by state.)[49]
While the gas tax is better
than the alternative of general revenue, or not paying for roads at all, it
doesn't address some important problems. Today’s gas tax does not:
1. Account
for cost inflation in the road sector.
2. Account
for rising fuel efficiency.
3. Pay
for the full cost of building and maintaining local roads.
4. Pay
for air pollution.
5. Pay
for the full cost of crashes, which are borne individually through worsened
health and life outcomes, and socially through the health care system.
6. Raise
revenue from vehicles that do not use gasoline for fuel.
7. Recover
full costs of pavement damage from heavy vehicles.66
8. Address
congestion, which requires time of day differentiation. Traffic congestion is a problem. It is not
getting measurably worse over the past decade, but it is not getting obviously
better. Even if traffic reduces in the aggregate, it won't disappear to zero in
the next decade.
In principle, the first two
points can be addressed with regular rate adjustments or indexing of the gas
tax. In practice, indexing has not been
popular in the US. Massachusetts voters recently overturned a legislative plan
to implement gas tax indexing there,[50]
and Wisconsin repealed their indexing.[51]
The public is uncomfortable writing a blank check to government, even if the
revenue is constitutionally dedicated to transportation in general or roads in
particular. The Federal gas tax was last raised in 1993, and in Minnesota in
2008 (and before that 1998), so rate adjustments from legislative bodies are
infrequent. Other states have raised gas taxes in recent years.[52]
The popularity of gas tax increases (and other sources of funding) among the
citizenry varies across polls, and depends precisely on the way the question is
framed.[53]
The third point can be addressed with a rate
increase and adjustment to formulas. There is nothing in principle preventing a
higher gas tax with funds returned to localities, in exchange for a reduction
in local tax rates. That it has not happened is an indicator it faces political
obstacles.
The fourth and fifth point can be addressed with a
pollution or carbon tax[54]
and distance-based insurance (pay-at-the-pump)[55]
respectively, though the exact rates for these externalities will remain
subject to controversy.
The sixth point cannot be
addressed with a gas tax, and is a rising problem, but not yet at the point of
crisis. This is discussed further below.
The seventh point could be
addressed with a weight-distance tax, as in Oregon.[56]
The eighth point is the most
salient immediate justification for moving away from a gas tax.
Congestion (queueing) occurs when demand exceeds supply for
a period of time at a location. This results in delay (higher than free flow
travel times) for travelers, which is an economic loss. It turns out that many transportation systems
management strategies are effective at the edge of congestion. For instance
ramp metering, the traffic light at the end of the freeway on-ramp that tells a
driver whether she can enter, is most effective by keeping traffic just below
the critical point at which congestion sets in. If traffic is far below that
critical point, there is no danger of significantly higher congestion in
letting an additional vehicle on to the roadway. If traffic is well past that
point, there is reduced value in not letting an additional vehicle on, traffic
will be stop-and-go in any case, though logically congestion dissipates faster
when fewer new vehicles are added to the road. It is near that critical point
where it matters most.
It is often noted that if just
10 percent of cars were removed during rush hour, there would be little or no
delay. This is true in a way. The problem would be the response of traffic. If
there were no delay or other penalty, more cars would try to travel at that time,
so getting rid of one slice of vehicles will induce another slice of vehicles
to travel.[57]
Overall though, despite induced demand, in general
higher prices deter demand,[58]
as marginal travelers shift routes, time of day, mode, destination, or forego
the trip altogether to avoid the higher price. After paying for toll collection
costs and the capital and operating costs of the toll facility in question, the
revenue from a publicly owned toll facility can offset other transportation
taxes, subsidize transportation investment, be returned to taxpayers, or be
invested in something else. What is done with the money is primarily a
political decision.
A transition from gas tax and
other sources of revenues to a vehicle weight-distance tax with prices varying
by time-of-day is a plausible path by which dynamic pricing can become
mainstream. Such a system might be phased in.
Economists have long suggested
using a price mechanism to allocate scarce road space. There are a variety of
approaches in practice.[59]
Several of these are discussed in the sections below.
7.2 Toll Roads
“Fuel taxes paid at the pump
[are] relatively invisible to the public, simple to collect, difficult to
evade, and collection and administration [are] inexpensive. In contrast, MBUF [is]
not easy to understand (especially the complexities and distaste of collecting
mileage and location information) and not as easy to collect.”[60]
Swenson et al. develop a scenario with toll roads as the path toward the same
end state, positing 25,000 miles of toll roads in 2050 (compared with 6000
miles in 2015).
US National Highway System
Toll roads and bridges, long
used as a simple infrastructure funding mechanism (often for bond repayment)
with fixed rates, have begun to implement prices that vary by time of day, so
that in addition to raising funds for a particular facility, they also manage
traffic on that same facility by charging more in the peak and less in the
off-peak.
Pricing is used in many sectors (including transportation:
notably all freight transportation, passenger aviation, and public transit), it
has been resisted on roads where it might do a great deal of good. (Despite the
various mechanisms, toll revenue is less than 1 percent of state transportation
funds in Minnesota, though it varies by state, and is over 46 percent in
Delaware, Nationally it is less than 6.9 percent of state transportation
revenue).[61]
This resistance stemmed
originally from the inefficiency of toll collection with toll booths, which
resulted in delay rather than relieving it (and were never billed as congestion
pricing, but were simply a revenue mechanism). With the advent of the
Electronic Toll Collection in the 1990s, resistance moved more toward questions
of “double taxation”, “equity” and “privacy”. In principle, the question of
double taxation is easily dealt with if other taxes are in fact reduced with
the introduction of pricing. Some equity implications are summarized in
Levinson (2010).79 Overall the equity issues depend on how the
system is implemented. However in a world of GPS, cell phones, EZ-Pass,80
and the NSA, few believe that toll collectors with electronic toll collection
systems will not be tracking the location of users, even with public sector
protestations and the development of privacy-protecting technologies.
The adoption of Electronic
Toll Collection to replace Manual Toll Collection is nearly complete. However
the deployment of new toll roads is barely faster than the construction of
roads overall.
Figure 1 shows the cumulative
mileage of toll roads in the US.81 Based on a logistic curve
extrapolated on current growth rates from 1987 forward, it would take until
2331 for half of the National Highway System (75,000 of 150,000 miles) to be
tolled. Expectations of new toll road construction with both constrained
resources and falling per capita demand, prospects for new toll roads are dim.
This is not to say there will
never be a new toll road in Minnesota, but this is unlikely to be significant
from a systems perspective. Several opportunities for new toll roads in the
past two decades (US 212, Mn610, the St. Croix River Bridge) have been foregone
in what were seemingly better circumstances than are expected for new
rights-of-way in coming years.
Based on the observed growth of toll roads in the US,
and the reluctance to convert existing roads to tolls, a major uptake of toll
roads is unlikely. The only untolled roads that have been successfully tolled
in the US are HOV lanes, which are on a different trajectory, and generally
remain free for HOV users (as discussed below).82
79 Levinson,
David (2010) Equity Effects of Road Pricing: A Review. Transport Reviews 30(1) 33-57. http://nexus.umn.edu/Papers/TransportEquityReviewPaper.pdf
80
Hirose, Mariko (2015) “Newly Obtained Records Reveal
Extensive Monitoring of E-ZPass Tags Throughout New York.” https://www.aclu.org/blog/free-future/newly-obtained-records-reveal-extensive-monitoring-e-zpass-tagsthroughout-new-york and Stanley, Jay (2015)
“Christie Use of Tollbooth Data and Why Location Privacy Must Be Protected” https://www.aclu.org/blog/free-future/christie-use-tollbooth-data-and-why-location-privacy-must-beprotected
81 Data for
Figure 1 comes from several sources:
Miles of Toll Roads http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/policyinformation/tollpage/miletrends.cfm http://ntl.bts.gov/lib/5000/5700/5741/toll95.pdf Accessed July 6, 2015
Toll Facilities in the United
States: February 1999 Publication No. FHWA-PL-99-011 Internet: http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/ohim (http://ntl.bts.gov/lib/21000/21900/21924/PB99148959.pdf) Accessed July 6, 2015 Toll
Facilities in the United States: Toll Mileage Trends — 2003 to 2013 (Interstate and Non-Interstate Bridges,
Tunnels, and Roads) Miles of Toll Bridges and Tunnels
TOLL FACILITIES IN THE UNITED
STATES Bridges - Roads - Tunnels - Ferries August 2009 Publication No:
FHWA-PL-09-00021 Internet: http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/ohim/tollpage.htm found at http://www.bv.transports.gouv.qc.ca/per/0961949/05_2009.pdf Accessed July 6, 2015
1940-1990 Data from International
Bridge Tunnel and Turnpike Association, Washington DC, reported in GomezIbanez
and Meyer Going Private p.169. Brookings Institution.
82 Note that
HOV occupancy restrictions sometimes do change, for instance from HOV-2 to
HOV-3.
NET: Conversion of existing untolled roads to tolls is also likely
to be a non-starter both due to collection costs and the expected political
pushback, particular if this is done selectively. Users of a road proposed for
conversion will complain about why their road is converted to tolls while
others aren’t.
7.3 Toll Areas
Cordon or area-based pricing
charges users crossing into or traveling within a particular congested area.
Prices vary by time of day to a greater or lesser degree of refinement. This
has been implemented in several cities, notably Singapore, Stockholm,
Gothenburg, Milan, and London. It has been proposed in several US cities,
including New York, San Francisco, and Washington DC, which all have natural
features (major rivers) that serve as logical cordons. None of those proposals
has yet made it off the drawing board.
NET:
Prospects for a London-style congestion cordon in Minnesota (for instance in
downtown Minneapolis) are unlikely. Many cities which have significantly more
congestion have yet to go forward with such a strategy. These systems are
expensive to implement on a per use basis, and while they are effective in
discouraging through trips in cities,
auto trips to cities can be more
easily metered with parking charges (at least until autonomous vehicles become
widespread, as discussed in Chapter 1).
7.4 Toll Lanes
High Occupancy/Toll (HOT)
lanes, including the local MnPASS system in Minnesota are separate lanes on an
existing facility that have prices varying by time-of-day or dynamically (in
real-time, based on actual traffic levels), while giving a discount (full or
partial) to high-occupancy vehicles. These lanes were historically conversions
of under-utilized HOV lanes, but many now are new construction.
The brightest spot in tolling today is the growth of HOT
Lanes in the United States, as shown in Figure 7.2. From a slow start in the
1990s, growth has picked up in the past decade significantly, with a number of
projects recently opened and many more underway. The graph shows projects that
are open, under construction, or with contracts signed. The number of projects
in planning stages are more still. While still a small share of the total
highway mileage in the United States (there are 4 million miles of streets and
roads in the US, the National Highway System has 150,000 miles, the Interstates
are 46,000 miles of that), it is growing rapidly, and should eventually absorb
the US HOV network and then some. Conversion of HOV lanes to HOT lanes itself
is too small to make an important difference (this has already taken place in
the Twin Cities region). Rather, if the system is to grow, sources of growth
will need to come from new capacity.
Applying a best-fit logistic
growth curve, at current rates of growth, HOT Lanes, projected at 722 lane
miles nationally in 2020 based on current and let projects, could grow to
10,000 lane miles by 2035, 32,000 in 2044, and 50,000 miles by 2050, on pace to
maximum of about 64,000 miles. In short, this rate of growth implies there will
be HOT Lanes on every mile of urban and suburban freeway, and perhaps on
selected arterials. Whether this is due to General Purpose lane conversion or
new construction cannot be determined from such simple modeling, and inevitably
will fit the context to some extent. To date it has been mostly new
construction, but this change needs to be seen in the context of vehicle
automation and more efficient use of existing pavement roadspace. This suggests
that as lanes are narrowed and new lanes created from existing lanes and
underutilized shoulders, some of those lanes will be Express or HOT lanes.
HOT lanes could be added to many regional highways as they
are expanded or reconfigured with narrower lanes (See Chapter 1), the current pace of 1 freeway every 6 years in a metro
area with so many freeways (2004: I-394, 2010:
I-35W S of Minneapolis, 20156: I-35E N of St. Paul) suggests about 5
decades before the entire Metro area freeway network has express toll lanes
available. And that does nothing for surface streets. Yet if the S-Curve is
correct, we should expect that growth to accelerate past the current local
rate.
Minnesota DOT has developed extensive plans for the
deployment of an Express Lanes (HOT Lane) Network. Two sections are already
open, and one is currently under construction, while others in various stages
of planning.[62]
The value of HOT lanes can be combined with the opportunity to use these lanes
for freeway-based Bus Rapid Transit (express buses) now, and as a separate
restricted network for Automated Vehicles in the future.
While currently HOT lane (and
toll systems in general) use different electronic toll collection systems,
federal requirements are moving towards interoperability, so out-of-region
travelers can use transponders to pay for toll route travel.
NET: HOT Lanes
are likely, but not significant from a system revenue perspective. The MnPASS
system currently serves fewer than 1 percent of Minnesotans daily. Deployment
remains slow, only as freeways are rebuilt.
No comments :
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.